2016/01/03

Keynes’s Battle over International Monetary System ―Between “Internationalist” System Designer and Political Pragmatist Toshiaki Hirai*          


  

    Keynes’s Battle over International Monetary      System
         
 Between “Internationalist” System Designer and Political Pragmatist

                                                      Toshiaki Hirai*


                     Abstract

The present paper forms part of a project which aims at examining the proposals Keynes put forward in regard to a postwar world economic order, and how they came to be transformed through actual political negotiations. The project covers, mainly, three targets – commodity problem, relief and reconstruction problem, and international monetary system. Some work for the former two has been done. The present paper now turns to the last one.
                             In the former two, the two facets are clearly recognizable in Keynes. On the one hand, Keynes as a system designer worked out proposals, which showed excellence of “internationalism”. On the other, he revealed himself, in the process of negotiations ― either domestic or international -, as a sort of political pragmatist who would defend or give clear priorities on the interests of the British Empire.
                          How about the sphere of international monetary system? To what degree did these two facets appear? This should be a main concern in this paper.
                           Thus the present paper has two objectives. One is to analyze the negotiations over how the postwar international monetary system should be built between the US and the UK in the first half of the 1940s. The other is to follow how Keynes’s two faces appeared in this process.
                           The paper runs as follows. Firstly we would see the Keynes’s plan. Secondly,
we would examine the negotiation process over international monetary system
between the US and the UK in chronological order which can be effectively
divided into three phases. Thirdly, we would examine Keynes’s stance. Finally,
we would refer to the significance which these studies might have in relation to
the current world monetary system ― sometimes referred to as a “non-system”
, for the argument developed there is, par excellence, of present significance.


  Key Words: International Clearing Union, International Stabilization Fund, Keynes, White, Bancor, Unitas


                                           1. Introduction

The present paper forms part of a project which aims at examining the proposals Keynes put forward in regard to a postwar world economic order, and how they came to be transformed through actual political negotiations. The project covers, mainly, three targets – commodity problem, relief and reconstruction problem, and international monetary system1. Some work for the former two has been done. The present paper now turns to the last one.
  In the former two, the two facets are clearly recognizable in Keynes. On the one hand, Keynes as a system designer worked out proposals, which showed excellence of “internationalism”. On the other, he revealed himself, in the process of negotiations either domestic or international -, as a sort of political pragmatist who would defend or give clear priorities on the interests of the British Empire.
  How about the sphere of international monetary system? To what degree did these two facets appear? This should be a main concern in this paper.
  Thus the present paper has two objectives. One is to analyze the negotiations over how the postwar international monetary system should be built between the US and the UK in the first half of the 1940s. The other is to follow how Keynes’s two faces appeared in this process.
  The paper runs as follows. Firstly we would see the Keynes’s plan. Secondly, we would examine the negotiation process over international monetary system between the US and the UK in chronological order which can be effectively divided into three phases. Thirdly, we would examine Keynes’s stance. Finally, we would refer to the significance which these studies might have in relation to the current world monetary system – sometimes referred to as a “non-system” -, for the argument developed there is, par excellence, of present significance.


          2Keynes Plan
            
               September 1941 - August 1942

The International Clearing Union Plan (the ICU or the Keynes Plan) was firstly presented on September 8 in 1941, earlier than the International Stabilization Plan (the White Plan). As Table 1 shows, it reached the version dated August 28 in 1942 after three revisions. As far as the Keynes Plan is concerned, this is the most fundamental one, so that it should be called the “genuine” Keynes Plan.

Table 1. Several ICU Plans
                                  - September 1941 to August 1942

Sep.8, 1941
Post-War Currency Policy
Sep.8, 1941
Proposals for an International Currency Union
(First Version)  
Sep.16, 1941
R.H.Brand sent Keynes E.F. Schumacher’s
memorandum, “Some Aspects of Post-war Economic Planning” which advocates international clearing arrangements.
Nov. 18, 1941
Proposals for an International Currency Union
(Second Version)
Dec.15, 1941
Proposals for an International Currency Union
(Third Version)
Jan.,1942
Plan for an International Currency (or Clearing) Union (Fourth Version)
April 15, 1942
Harrod wrote to Keynes a proposal to set up an Anglo-American economic service for the postwar world economic order, which deals with the ICU, a buffer stock plan, a relief and reconstruction plan, and an international capital flow control plan.
August 28, 1942
Proposals for an International Clearing Union (“genuine” ICU Plan)


2.1 The Proposal for an ICU dated August 28 1942

The “genuine” ICU proposal basically runs as follows.

(i) The “parity” of a member nation defined as the exchange rate between its currency and “bancor” (to be explained later) is set up on agreement among the member nations. Thereafter, when fundamental disequilibrium occurs, the nation concerned is allowed to change the parity subject to consultation. Therefore, the ICU adopts a kind of fixed exchange rate system.
     Bancor is an international currency only used between central banks. It has a fixed exchange rate with gold. Each central bank of a member state has its own account in terms of bancor, through which international settlement is to be made. All the international transactions are carried to a bancor account of a central bank concerned. A firm, which exports (imports) goods, receives (pays) currency  required at a fixed rate in exchange for an export (import) bill from (to) a central bank concerned. Though a foreign exchange market exists and firms or individuals are free to exchange foreign currencies there, the rate is set up, in advance, at a fixed rate by agreement. Even if the rate departs from the parity, it will reach the parity soon.
      It should be noted that an adjustment is not made by the intervention of a government but through a deal between a central bank and firms or individuals which would compare the parity with the exchange rate. In that sense, the ICU system is closer to the Gold Standard than the IMF system which operated up to the 1960s, albeit all the three are fixed exchange rate systems. In the former two a government does not interfere with a foreign exchange market and directly transacts with firms or individuals, while in the latter a government interferes with the foreign exchange market but not directly transacts with them.
 
(ii) The ICU proposal stipulates that, in order to prevent a persistent increase in the balance of payments of a member nation in both surplus and deficit direction, penalty should be imposed on it if the sum exceeds a prescribed value.

(iii) The ICU proposal stipulates that, in order to contribute to the growth in the world economy, overdraft facilities should be provided.
 
(iv) The ICU proposal advocates that, in order to provide funds for the primary commodity problem and the relief problem which the postwar world economy should be faced with, international institutions concerned should open their own bancor accounts.

Let us see how the basic mechanism of the ICU works, in which all the transactions are cleared through the bancor accounts of central banks of member states, by means of a simple example.
  Suppose that 1 bancor = 1 dollar = 2 pounds (at parity), and the London Automobile Co. exports a car for 1 dollar to the Washington Co.
The Smith Automobile Co. receives an export bill from the Washington Co., and hand it over to the Bank of England for 2 pounds. The BOE, in turn, hands the bill to the FRB. On this occasion, on the BOE’s account 1 bancor is credited while on the FRB’s account 1 bancor is debited. The FRB hands over the bill to the Washington Co. in exchange for 1 dollar. Thus the transaction is cleared.
The ICU plan is consciously presented as correcting the shortcoming of the Gold Standard. In the Gold Standard, the parity is fixed by the agreement among the member states while the foreign exchange market freely operates through the operations of firms and individuals. As a result the exchange rate fluctuates. And yet is supposed to remain within the range of the exporting point of gold, at which a central bank sells and buys gold. In the Gold Standard, however, each country has no discretionary room for economic policy and is racked by the waves of an international movement of gold.2


2.2 A Sketch of a Transition of International Monetary System  up to the Present Day

Before examining the two plans – the Keynes Plan and the White Plan, it might be better to describe the path briefly along which international monetary system has came to follow from the summer of 1942 to the present day.
It was in the summer of 1942 when the White Plan (Stabilization Fund) appeared as a rival of the ICU plan. According to this plan, the parity of each member state is to be determined on the agreement among the member states, and an obligation of its maintenance is to be imposed on a member state. Therefore, if the exchange rate is deviated from the parity, a member state should be responsible for maintaining the parity through the operation in the foreign exchange market. If the fundamental disequilibrium should occur, a change in the parity is to be permitted upon agreement.
As will be explained later, it was the IMF system based on the White plan rather than the ICU plan that came to be adopted as the postwar international monetary system. Although both plans adopt a fixed exchange rate system, there is a fundamental difference. The ICU plan has a “bancor” as an international money, and is equipped with a facility to create credit, through which it could conquer an obstacle to economic growth due to shortage of international liquidity.
The White plan, on the other hand, retained the feature of the Gold Standard, and was the de facto Dollar Standard, in which the movement of dollars was to have great influences on the world economy. Based on the subscriptions from the member states, the IMF was set up for this international system. Each member state subscribed the agreed quota either in gold or its own currency. The fundamental role of the IMF was, while overseeing the economic situation of the member states, to make a short-run loan to a member state which fell into shortage in liquidity. As the IMF system was not equipped with the facility of credit creation, the liquidity problem of the world economy was to be determined, after all, by the movement of dollars, which means that the world economy is to be influenced by the condition of the US economy and its economic policy. The dollar shortage problem immediately after the Second World War, the dollar crisis due to the deficit in the US trade balance, and the creation of the SDR as a solution for liquidity shortage in the 1960s were the phenomena to epitomize it. This was a system adopted up until the Nixon Shock in 1971.
  As is well known, the world has, thereafter, adopted a flexible exchange rate system up until now. In this system there exists no parity, for, because all the international transactions are left to the foreign exchange markets, it does not need something like a parity. Instead, however, there is a high possibility that the rates determined there might not be “appropriate”, subject to violent fluctuations mainly due to speculative activities. That is why, some sort of appropriate exchange rate (e.g. purchasing power parity) might be required there.


3. The Two Plans Compared

Summer 1942 (starting point) - April 1943            
]   (announcement)

It was until the summer of 1942 when the two plans were exchanged and started to be examined among the persons concerned. As a result of these process thereafter, both plans were publicized in April 1943 (see Table 2). In this section, we would examine the Keynes plan as publicized and Keynes’s evaluation of the White plan as publicized.

 Table 2 The Two Plans Compared
         Summer 1942 - April 1943

July 22, 1942

Keynes received the White Plan from Phillips. (note: Thereafter it was revised eight times before Keynes received it around Feb. 1943.)

Phillips’ preliminary discussion with (US) Berle, Pasvolsky and White over the ICU plan.
Sep. 23, 1942
Keynes’s discussion with (US) Winant and Riefler
Oct.23, 1942
A long discussion between Keynes and White over the two plans
The end of Oct., 1942
Keynes explanation of the ICU to the representatives of the Dominions
Nov.9,1942
Another version of the ICU plan
Dec.11, 1942
Introduction of “Unitas” into the White plan
March 1, 1943
April 16, 1943
The two plans compared by Keynes
Notes on I.C.U. and I.S.F. by Keynes
April 7, 1943
the White plan publicized
the ICU plan published as the White Paper (Cmd 6437
April 27, 1943
On the White plan by Keynes


3.1 International Clearing Union Plan (April 7, 1943)


In April 7, 1943, both the International Clearing Union Plan (the ICU) was publicized (on the same day the White Paper (Cmd.6437) was also publicized).
  Keynes wrote the preface to it. Here Keynes states that there are four international spheres to allow for: (1) currency and exchange mechanism; (2) framework for commercial policy, (3) primary commodities, and (4) aid to investment. As the conditions which should be emphasized in setting up international economic systems for these spheres, the following are mentioned:

   (1) to minimize the interference with domestic spheres.
(2) to make a planning technique applicable irrespective of types of the member states.
(3) to make administration and management of international organizations concerned be genuinely international.
(4) to give the member states a withdrawal option.
(5) to make a planning concerned be managed for the sake of the overall and particular benefits of the member states.

That said, Keynes makes clear that for a state (e.g. the UK) which should face the relief and reconstruction in the postwar period, a proposal to be preferentially implemented in the first sphere should be the International Clearing Union.
Concerning the ICU, Keynes refers to the following.

(1) The ICU does not make a long-term loan.
(2) The ICU should be responsible for preventing an economic growth in the world as a whole from being spoiled because surplus member states should go on holding a huge sum of balances. The ICU is aware that it could pave a new path by making not only deficit member states but also surplus ones accept responsibility for international persistent disequilibrium.
                               
3.2 The Two Plans Reviewed (April 16, 1943)

Keynes wrote a memorandum, dated April 16, 1943, on the Clearing Union Plan and the Stabilized Plan (the SF or the White Plan) as follows.

(1) Voting Power. Keynes does not stick to the power of voting. However, he thinks that there is a problem with the SF rule to the effect that all the decisions should require four fifth majority and that special matters should require three fourths, while the other matters should be OK with a simple majority.

   (2) Gold. Keynes thinks that as far as treatment of gold is concerned, there is less difference between the two than the media causes a stink. He states, however, that the SF plan has no provision for changing the gold value of unitas, and that unitas is of no use at all. Therefore, it is necessary to activate unitas. (Although it was in Dec. 11, 1942 when unitas came to be introduced into the White plan, little or no significance was attached to it. Cf. pp.233-448.)

(3) Multilateral Clearing. Keynes states that the SF plan has no provision for multilateral clearing, so that it should be revised. He sees, however, the difficulty of revising it.

(4) The Scale of Quotas. The fundamental difficulty recognizable in the SF plan is that the desire for debtor countries to get currencies of some particular creditor countries far exceeds the ability of the Fund to provide them (Cf. p.247).

(5) “Abnormal War Balances” problem – that is, “Sterling Balances” problem. As the war proceeded, the UK, for example, was to owe huge sum of debts to India. If these debts were replaced by, say, dollar - scarce currency - by India, the UK would face great financial difficulties. This is a problem referred to here.

 (6) The Rationing of Scarce Currencies. But for this provision, the logic of the whole plan would go broke, and yet it would be extremely difficult to work out a practical plan.

(7) Subscribed Capital vs. Banking Principle. This is the most controversial point over which we should be most hesitant to make compromise. Keynes states that we should observe the banking principle, going to such an extent that if we could do so, we might make compromise in the rest of the matters.


4. Integration Process of the Two Plans
 June 1943 – April 1944

After the public announcement of the two plans, there naturally followed the task of discussing and negotiating how they should be integrated. This negotiation process can be divided into two. One is an offense and defense over the “monetization of unitas”, which was a persuasion process from the Keynes side to incorporate a flavor of bancor into unitas, while putting the main basis on the White plan. This indicates that on the negotiation table between the two states the Keynes plan was treated as a secondary plan from the beginning which the UK side tacitly acknowledged. The other is the final phase of the negotiation, which was to be determined overwhelmingly in the form of the White plan. 
  Let us examine each of them in details (Table 3 summarizes the process
concerned).

  Table 3 The Integration Process of the Two Plans
June 1943 - April 1944
June 29, 1943
Integration of the C.U. and the S.F. by Keynes
(and yet based on the S.F.)
July 19, 1943
Keynes’s comment on the White plan (July 10
version)
Sep. 21, 1943
Proposal to monetize Unitas
  (White showed opposition to it.
Oct. 1943
The relation between the two sides deteriorated.
Oct. 12, 1943
Anglo-American Draft Statement of Principles
April 22, 1944
Joint Statement by Experts on the Establishment of an International Monetary Fund (Cmd. 6519)

                            


4.1 Offense and Defense over the Monetization of Unitas
 – June 1943 to October 1943

In June 1943 an unofficial conference between the US and the UK was held in Washington. On this occasion Keynes wrote a memorandum titled “The Synthesis of C.U. and S.F.” dated June 29. In spite of the title, it was, in fact, based on the White plan, putting the Keynes plan on the shelf, advocating that the Fund should adopt unitas.
  Reading the White plan (dated July 10) thereafter, he sent a letter (dated July 19) to Eady, revealing his stern view.

In my judgment we must be prepared to face a complete breakdown unless
important changes are made (p.316).

    I submit that our delegation should be instructed to break off negotiations for
the time being unless satisfactory concessions can be obtained on the three
essentials … (p.320).

The “three essentials” run as follows.

(1) To make a change in the value of a member’s currency much more elastic,
preserving sovereignty in this respect.

(2) The Fund should monetize unitas and perform multilateral clearing.
(“The Fund must not deal in a mixed bag of currencies but only in unitas” [p.317]).

  (3) Gold subscription for a member should be 12.5% rather than 25%.

In a letter dated September to White, Keynes put forward, for the first time, “monetization of unitas” (pp.342-344). The gist of it was an attempt to reform the SF like the ICU – that is, each member state should be to open an account within the SF, through which multiple clearing is to be made (pp.342-343). This is stated, however, given that unitas should be used together with other currencies, so that it seems to step back as compared with the argument shown in the above letter to Eady dated July 19.
  Concretely speaking, his proposal runs as follows:

As it stands, unitas has no function to play, so let us adopt unitas - together with dollar and pound - as international currency which, however, exists only on the accounts of the central banks of the member countries.
      Suppose, for example, that the UK sells 100 pounds to the US. Given 1 pound = 1 unitas, the UK can get 100 unitas from the US and credit it with its unitas account, while the US debits 100 unitas and gets 100 pounds. The two have an obligation to use unitas on the one side of buying and selling.
      That indicates that each member has a “bag” which contains gold, dollar, and unitas (as an account unit). The Fund also possesses the same kind of “bag”.

 This is monetization of unitas proposed by Keynes. It should be noted that it is quite different, in nature, from bancor.
   Bancor is a system in which all the international transactions are to be cleared through transfer between the bancor accounts of central banks, which means that  dollar and pounds do not appear at this stage. Among other things, there does not exist foreign exchange markets. In the plan for monetization of unitas, on the other, unitas is used as money in the same way as dollar and pound are. Although, in form, it might look like bancor, it is quite different in essence. In this type of unitas, international transactions are made through the foreign exchange market, so that each central bank is required to interfere with it in order to maintain its parity.
 Let us see the two provisions which Keynes put forward.
  
A member should try to sell its own currency to other members in exchange for the transfer of unitas at parity on the account of the Fund.

A member should try to buy other member’s currency from other member, so far as it holds unitas balances, in exchange for the transfer of unitas at parity on the account of the Fund.

That is, e.g. when the UK sells pounds to the US, it should get equivalent units of unitas at parity on the account, while when the UK buys dollars from the US, it should pay equivalent units of unitas at parity on the account.
 
In September 24, 1943 a joint meeting of the U.K. and U.S. was held at the U.S.
Treasury. The U.K. side had, besides Keynes, a group of brilliant economists such
as Robertson, Robbins and Meade3 while the U.S. side was occupied by civil
servants. White was not there.
On that day, the meeting proceeded with Keynes as a key player, who made comments on the White plan, suggesting points for improvement. It was mainly Bernstein at the U.S. Treasury who responded to Keynes.
Keynes put forward two proposals. One was an agenda to make access to the Fund certain, while the other was around the monetization of unitas.
Concerning the former, Keynes argued that the Fund should make it possible for a member to borrow up to 120% of the subscription. This was proposed to alleviate a risk that the room for domestic policy might be small. As to subscription, Keynes proposed that subscription in gold should be confined up to 12.5% of the whole amount, and the subscription made in gold and securities should be regarded as “collateral”. (It is offered as collateral rather than subscription. This is a point of view of the country which possesses small amount of gold.)
 The above was able to be written in terminology of the S.F. The following proposals, however, were not so easily dealt with.

(
1) Unqualified multilateral clearing (the point which Keynes emphasized most)
(2) The duty of members to maintain exchange stability (Different from the Keynes plan, management of foreign exchange markets remains important in the White plan.)
(3) The passivity of the Fund (an unitas account represents it. This is true of the
Keynes plan)

The following is an example of the discussion between Keynes and Bernstein at the meeting.
Keynes said that “Britain wanted a system which looked different and was different from the pre-war system. … the S.F. provision that the amounts of the Fund should be kept in unitas, contained the germ of agreement on the subject” (p.348). Bernstein responded that “no magic could disguise the fact that the Fund might be short of particular currencies even in utitas terms.”
Keynes replied that “[I do] not dispute this as a matter of logic but [I] prefer the concept of a monetized unitas to express a generalized currency, or claim on the world at large.” Bernstein further responded that “the Treasury Group [sees] merit in all the points put forward by the United Kingdom Group, but would want to discuss them separately with the State Department. It might be difficult to persuade the bankers on several of the proposals” (p.349).

In a letter to Eady dated October 3, 1943 Keynes reported the situation in
Washington. He said that he is wholeheartedly welcome in Washington, quite different from his last visit around the Pearl Harbor attack. Among others, he said he felt great comfort there because of Lippmann and Acheson4. Then he described his remarks of the persons whom he met there5. Let us introduce some of them below.

I have seen quite a lot of Berle, who is a queer attractive, unattractive figure in disequilibrium with himself and the world. One never knows in what direction he will rush off. But he has been extremely helpful and generally tending to take our side in the discussions. (p.354)


Keynes refers to some officials in the State Department. Among others, a
description of Laughlin Currie should be worth attention.

Currie is an old friend of mine and I know him well, but there is no one more difficult to handle. He is extremely suspicious and jealous, very anti-British on such issues as India, and always inclined to assume the worst. (p.356)

A description of White is also interesting.

    He is over-bearing, a bad colleague, always trying to bounce you, with harsh rasping voice, aesthetically oppressive in mind and manner; he has not the faintest conception of how to behave or observe the rules of civilised intercourse. At the same time, I have a very great respect and even liking for him. In many respects he is the best man here. … Moreover, his over-powering will combined with the fact that he has constructive ideas mean that he does get things done, which few else here do. He is not open to flattery in any crude sense. The way to reach him is to respect his purpose, arouse his intellectual interest … (p.356)

Then follows a report on the negotiation as the main theme. Firstly Keynes mentions five points from the British side which are thought to be acceptable to the U.S. side as follows.

(1) elasticity of the exchange rates
(2) the formula for changing the gold value of unitas
 (3) an increase of the quotas to 12 billion dollars
(4) the amount of the gold subscription
(5) a system extremely severe on scarce currency

On the other, Keynes points out problems which are difficult to agree as follows.

(1) the British claim that gold subscription should be regarded as a pledge
(2) the US claim that the Fund should be given more discretion in members’ using the Fund (the British side claims passivity on the activity of the Fund)
(3) the US opposition to monetization of unitas

Among others, the most point in dispute was the “monetization of unitas”.

(The US) are adamant against the monetization of unitas and hold out strongly for the mixed bag of currencies. They admit that our proposals are immeasurably better on merits, but declare that it is only by putting on this very peculiar fancy dress (a bag which contains dollar and pound but no unitas) that they can get the thing through their own bankers…. (p.359)

Keynes grows distrustful of this attitude.

    … there is nothing more difficult than to continue a controversy with people   
who admit that your proposal is immeasurably better than their own but nevertheless hold out on the ground that for obscure psychological reasons only theirs is practical politics. (p.360)

Keynes turned to Bernstein for his attack.

Both the currency scheme and the investment scheme are, I think, largely the fruit of the brain not of Harry [White] but of his little attaché, Bernstein. (p.364)

Keynes threw him in the roast as follows.
                                     
   … when we seduce Harry from the true faith, little Bernstein wins him back again in the course of the night. Bernstein is a regular little rabbi, a reader out of the Talmud, to Harry’s grand political high rabbidom. He is very clever and rather sweet, but knows absolutely nothing outside the turns and twists of his mind. (p.364)

The “investment scheme” referred to above, in fact, had been simultaneously   discussed with the international monetary plan. Concerning this, Keynes sent three letters to Eady on October 3, 1943, in the third one of which Keynes sated as follows.
Concerning the international investment plan, White’s very mysterious action surprised many people around him. He presented it, out of blue, to the Congress, asking to make it public at the same time. Keynes, who knew it, reproached him severely. White apologized Keynes for his misbehavior, promising not to repeat that sort of behavior.
White’s proposal was very queer. In Keynes’s judgment, it contained a sincere motive to save the situation if it would have been described well. But in fact, it was presented in such a way as would make the people understand it in quite the contrary way. 
Keynes remarks that it is also true of the “mixed bag of currencies” in the monetary scheme.

He may be right in thinking the United States is 25 years out of date, and that no American banker will accept anything unless first of all it look entirely imbecile, but are people really so silly, or if so silly, so easily deceived as all that? It is rather a tragedy. For there are some very good ideas and immensely disinterested, fine international purpose in the scheme. (pp. 363-364)

The atmosphere of the conference held on October 4 was what could be said to be dismal. A participant from the UK expressed the situation as follows.

 What absolute Bedlam these discussions are! Keynes and White sit next [to]  
each other, each flanked by a long row of his own supporters. Without any agenda or any prepared idea of what is going to be discussed they go for each other in a strident duet of discord, which after a crescendo of abuse on either side leads up to a chaotic adjournment of the meeting in time for us to return to the Willard for a delegation meeting. (p.364)

Under that atmosphere, limitation to drawing rights, the meaning of rare currency, constraint of an exchange rate within 10-20% around the initial parity and so forth were discussed.



4.2 The Final Phase of the Negotiation
 - October 6, 1943 – April 22, 1944

The meeting on October 6, 1943 saw a significant development. It agreed to set up a committee for writing a draft in terms of the Stabilization Fund, which was to determine the details of the Fund. After this meeting was over, Keynes wrote a letter to White, showing the view of the British Government, which contains the following three points.

(1) “the preference for a system under which an alteration in the exchanges requires only consultation and not formal approval by voting”.
(2) instructions to aim at the monetization of unitas

Concerning this point, Keynes states as follows.

Reserving our position as to the form in which the Fund is set up. London emphasises that they are not at present prepared to release us from our instructions to aim at the monetisation of unitas ... (p.367)

(3) subscription in gold should be regarded as reserve.

In his letter to Eady dated October 8, Keynes highly esteemed the discussion at the
House of Commons while he threw harsh criticism of that in the House of Lords.
What interest us in this letter is a description of Morgenthau, the Secretary of the
Treasury.

An experienced American told us the other day that during the ten years of Morgy’s reign the U.S. Treasury has devoted its whole efforts to appeasing a non-existent public sentiment, and has invariably failed to be even dimly aware of the public sentiments which really exist. (p.369)

And Keynes points out the lack in governability in the US (p.370).
On October 8 and 9, a task of drawing a draft was carried out. Although eventually this was to go well, there occurred a great turmoil on the eve of it. It was mainly due to Bernstein who made a proposal at the last minute such as returning back to the initial stage. This point is also described in Keynes’s letter to Eady dated October 10. There he stated in detail that it was Bernstein, White’s subordinate, who became the largest obstacle in the negotiation.    

He made a last minute effort to win back the ground he had lost, by persuading White, at the end of our meeting on Saturday morning, to produce a document for us to sign on which the Directive was to be interpreted, which brought about half of S.F. right back again [in] the exact words which the Talmudist wrote many months ago and has never been willing to alter, if he could help it, by an iota. … I, therefore, at the end of the morning meeting reacted rather violently, saying that it was really intolerable at the eleventh hour to have all these matters re-opened in exactly the same terms that we had started with before the discussion began. The other members of my Group thought I had overdone it, but after we had left the meeting a telephone message came along half an hour later that the paper was withdrawn… It was one example, in my judgment, of how important it is in this country to react strenuously. (pp.372-373)

Thereafter the drafting procedure went well and finally reached an important draft titled “Anglo-American Draft Statement of Principles”. As is evident from his letter to his mother (cf. p.374), Keynes was very much satisfied with it. Keynes’s appreciation of White is very high notwithstanding his weird behavior.

Yet all the same, I hold to the opinion which I have already expressed, that taking everything into account Harry White is probably just about the best man here, and the most serviceable to all concerned. (p.373)

Anglo-American Draft Statement of Principles”, which should be a very important official document between the two states, was prepared on October 12. The draft was very weird in that it was, in substance, the White plan void of unitas, showing the monetization of unitas, which the UK insisted upon, only as a sort of appendix (As will be later explained, in the Joint Statement issued on April 22, 1944, unitas was completely to disappear).
  As the subtitle of the Anglo-American Draft Statement – “Joint Statement by Experts of United and Associated Nations on the Establishment of an International Stabilisation Fund” – shows, this is put forward completely based on the White plan.
Before the main text is stated, the following phrase is inserted by the British side.

(The following draft is intended to set out and illustrate certain principles. It is expressed in terms of a Fund which holds members’ currencies. This form of expression has been used to meet the convenience of the United States Treasury and in no way commits the British representatives to recommend acceptance of such a form.) (pp.379-380)

This seems to reflect the US side’s treatment to save the face of the UK side. And, moreover, we see the British plan after the Draft Statement of Principles, beginning with the following sentence. However, it could be said to be of no use.
It states that the proposal without unitas shown in the main text can be expressed even if unitas is introduced. This is no more than the intention of the British side to cover up the defeat.

(V) The Draft Statement of Principles in Terms of a Monetised Unitas)
In order to express the substance of the Draft Statement of Principles in terms of monetized unitas, the following paragraphs should be substituted for those carrying the same number in the Draft discussed with the American group:- (p.389)

It should be also noted that Keynes’s stance concerning the monetization of unitas was transformed (or receded) from the initial stance that the Fund should use only unitas as international money to the later stance that unitas should be considered to be one element in the basket which contains dollar and pound as well. The above change belongs to the latter one.

Due to the above-mentioned difficult situation of the negotiation in October as shown above – the dismal atmosphere in the committee, White’s mysterious behavior, Bernstein’s obstructionist operation at the last minute and so forth this international negotiation almost went bust. Give this situation, the two states managed to reach an agreement by a hair’s breadth, so that we can understandably see how glad Keynes was to get the draft. And yet this was no more than Keynes’s stance as a policy maker. When he stood as a designer of an international system, he must have had a poor opinion of Keynes as a policy maker.
 In his letter to Opie dated December 7, 1943, Keynes’s stance, moreover, toned down, stating that we needed not adhere to the monetization of unitas. Here he pointed out the following two problems.

 (1)The importance of adhering to the monetized unitas version
(2)The need of being clearer about what happens during the transitional period

Having said that, he argues that it is (2) that is now important (p.393), which means his adherence to (1) attenuated. This is also recognizable in the following.

I have every natural reason for vastly preferring this set-up. [But] I cannot persuade myself that the difference between the two versions is really such as to make it a justifiable reason for an ultimate breach. (p.394)

In short, Keynes came to approve the Anglo-American Draft Statement.

Eady wrote a very useful document (dated January 19, 1944) which describes the situation around this period well. From this one could hear the discordance in the UK with the plan which Keynes brought back.
It was Keynes and Robertson who whole-heartedly approved the Draft. In the case of Keynes, he judged that the Draft was too insufficient for the UK to procure necessary funds, so a loan negotiation with the US should be indispensable (In fact, Keynes was to succeed in making the UK get a huge loan from the US through the Anglo-American Financial Agreement of December 1945.). 
  It was the Bank of England which strongly opposed the Draft for the following reasons: The power of discretion which it had enjoyed might be greatly reduced; the existence of the sterling balance problem6; doubt of “passiveness” of the Fund; a fear that management of the Fund might be governed by the US.
  There were persons such as Waley and Henderson who were not earnest in supporting the Draft, and rather saw it critically.  
The following passage which Eady revealed in the document is very impressive.

General framing of the scheme.
Although very substantial modifications have been made general structure of scheme is the same original American scheme. Attitude and technique is derived from Equalisation Fund technique … (p.397)

In February 7, 1944 Keynes almost approved the US plan.

     Under the Stabilisation Fund proposals the institution was to bank with the member countries, holding accounts with their central banks on which it would be free to operate in terms of each member’s currency, so that no new international unit would be necessary. An international money of account, unitas, was mentioned in the Stabilisation Fund proposals but was only mentioned to be forgotten and played no effective part. Now this difference [between the S.F. and the C.U.], however important, is nevertheless only a matter of technical form. A given set of proposals can be drafted in terms of either set-up so as to be identical in substance and legal effect. (p.405)

Here Keynes states that the difference between the ICU and SF is no more than a problem of technical form, and that unitas itself is unnecessary.

… we cannot enter into this scheme [IMF system] unless there is an assurance of our not being expected to use its facilities prematurely, and … we cannot have any such assurance until they have given us some indication of the financial regime succeeding the lend lease phase which should, in their opinion, assist a steady progress by ourselves and others into the period when equilibrium can be secured without large-scale assistance from outside. (p.407)

Keynes states that it might be wise to get an early opportunity to candidly tell it to the US Administration

We knew from Eady’s document written on January 19 how divided the UK was over the Anglo-American Draft Statement. The same is recognizable in the comment which Lord Cherwell made to the Prime Minister on February 9. According to it, there was an antagonism between the two factions. One was the Keynes faction which was supported by most of the Treasury, the Economic Section and the Board of Trade. The other was the Bank of England faction which was supported by Henderson and Eady.
On February 11, the War Cabinet agreed to set up a “Committee on External Economic Policy” to determine how it should issue an instruction. Keynes described the discussion in the committee as “a complete bedlam” (A letter to Waley dated February 17. See p.409).
  The committee issued a report on February 18, which almost reflected Keynes’s view (cf. p.409). Against it Beaverbrook submitted a dissent document. He argued that an alternative plan should be worked out through consultation with the BOE (p.410). The War Cabinet allowed deliberations to proceed along the lines by the majority report.
Keynes’s stance declared on February 7 was also clearly expressed in the memorandum to the Chancellor dated February 23. This was a pragmatic stance to try to establish an “Anglo-American Bloc Offered as an International Scheme”. This expression vividly reflects his state of mind. He felt much practical attraction in it, for there the UK can maintain the dignity of the British Empire as a central player together with the US, and yet it is proposed as an international scheme.
Contrastingly, The “Sterling Currency Bloc” was an idea of currency zone excluding the US. Given the present powers of the US, this would be completely broken down, and lead to the dissolution of the British Empire itself (Remember the Anglo-American Reciprocal Aid Agreement in February of 1942, in which the biggest point in dispute was the abolition of the imperial preference tariff. See vol.23, pp.194-228). If it comes to “Dollar Diplomacy”, the US only would rule the roost, and there would be no room for the British Empire to play. Thinking that way, Keynes endorsed an “Anglo-American Bloc Offered as an International Scheme”.
Here Keynes repeated the importance of getting a loan from the US.
       
    We are in no position, therefore, to set up as international bankers, undertaking large and not closely defined liabilities, unless we can secure a general settlement on the basis of temporary American assistance followed by an international scheme. (p.412)
 
Now that the effort to reform the Stabilization Fund plan through monetization of unitas failed, the Keynes plan as the International Clearing Union came to be completely defeated.
On March 8 Keynes sent a letter to Beaverbrook, who supported the BOE’s view.
It was a harsh criticism of the BOE (p.417), to which Beaverbrook responded, defending the stance of the BOE. 
  In a letter to White dated March 18, Keynes sent a message to the effect that he
would not make the unitas problem a condition for concluding an agreement.

The result of this was that you and Opie were able to arrive at a text, which was complete in respect of the discussions up to that point, except the question of the unitas version. Personally, I think it most unlikely that we shall make unitas a condition of acceptance, but we are not yet in a position to tell you so officially. (pp.427- 428)

On March 21 the discussion of the UK with the British Dominion in which
Keynes played a leading role, ended. It was agreed there that although the monetization of unitas would be desirable, we should not adhere to it (p.429).
In a letter to Eady dated March 29, Keynes states the following.
One is his argument that the relationship of a monetary scheme with other schemes is important (p.430). This could be said to be remnants of his idea which grasped the postwar order in total perspectives. The other is the necessity of Opie’s informing White on whether we should approve the unitas point. The sooner the better (p.431).
What was now going to be decided was to be finally decided in the international conference (in fact, in the Breton Woods Conference). To Keynes, however, all these matters seemed to be terribly confused and were not worthy of serious consideration (p.432).
On April 14 the British Cabinet agreed to the public announcement of the “Joint Statement”. On April 16 Keynes issued the following warning: If it should be regarded as a behavior which betray the promise with the US, we would take quid pro quo from the US, which would seriously worsen our situation.

     If our attitude can be construed, not perhaps legitimately but plausibly, as a departure from, or repudiation of, our obligation under Article VII of the Mutual Aid Agreement. I have not a doubt that the Americans will retaliate by withdrawing from the rest of this Agreement. This could mean our losing the sheet-anchor of our post-war settlement of lend lease, namely the undertaking that the ultimate aggrangement shall not be “such as to burden commerce”. (p.435)

In April 1944 Keynes made a comment on an important deliberation in the House
of Commons – the one over the Empire unity, especially Preferential Customs
(Article 7 of the Reciprocal Aid Agreement). He said that the anti-America and the
pro-British Empire sentiment was prevalent there. Although this should be a
transitory problem and not be a problem in the long term, we need to be careful of
it for the moment.
Keynes was sure that the Anglo-American cooperation should definitely make progress in the long term.

The Americans are also, I suppose, both in their relations with us and with others, suffering from the usual prejudice against a benefactor. That does not alter the fact that, one way or another, the point is being reached when the average man finds it very difficult to keep his temper or conceal his feelings. (p.447)

On April 22 Keynes wrote “Explanatory Notes by UK Experts on the Proposal for an IMF” (Cmd 6519) for the Joint Statement, in which he definitely said that we need neither bancor neither unitas (p.438).

In his letter to Opie dated April 23, Keynes vividly described his feeling at the time and the whole atmosphere. He stated that he got a permission from the British Government to the effect that he can say to White that he would not adhere to the unitas version any longer. It was sent Opie immediately after he left the UK.
But it reached Opie later than expected, which not only was to put the negotiation on a disadvantageous position but also was to be used by the White side as a sort of ultimatum..
Keynes said that he was not individually complain of White’s adoption of ultimatum, for it was mainly due to the delay and confusion in the British response.
Keynes was at that time preoccupied with how he could persuasively present the document to the public. He said that he could do well to the mass media, and was to meet a group of MPs for the same purpose.
We can also see the reference to the situation of the US side. Cordell Hull earnestly supported the IMF, behind which there is a backing, naturally, from the Roosevelt Administration. Roosevelt would emphasize the international cooperation in the economic field as the pledge in the Presidential election. He continuously built up international cooperation in the economic field such as POFA, UNRRA, ILO and so forth. Then would come the IMF and the IBRD. Keynes applauded these activities.

    All these projects taken together can be represented as a formidable first step towards international collaboration over the economic field. (p.445)

The above is what is desirable to us, and it is important not to obstruct the President’s action. Keynes stressed that we must never make quarrels with the US.
And yet, he added, we had better not act in such a way that we should support him in earnest, for the President himself does not want his move to show the Anglo-American outlook.
  Keynes’s stance was clear-cut. The UK has no strength to take an independent line, resisting the US. Even if it would do that way, it would doom to fail in front of the strength of the US, and would be driven into the collapse of the British Empire. What matters now is to build a cooperative relation with the US, avoiding conflicts. In this way the British Empire and the British banking could stand on barely an equal standing as the US in the center of the world in the same way as before. There would be no way for the British Empire to survive other than this.
  During the period from Keynes’s return from the US to April next year, the above draft was revised seven times. Moggridge sums up the negotiation process between the UK and the US during this period, which can be shown as Table 4. As is clearly seen at first sight, almost all the points of revision came from the US side and were accepted by the British side.7

 Table 4 The Final Phase of the Negotiation
           October 6, 1943 - April 22, 1944

Problem of contribution by gold
Acceptance of the American view in December plan.
Problem of sterilization
of contribution
Acceptance of the American view in December (The Fund can use gold for transaction). The UK regarded it as collateral.
Payment of withdrawal in gold
Acceptance of the American view (when a member country buys other member country’s money by gold from the Fund.)
Withdrawal of money for capital
Acceptance of the American view in January
Monetization of unitas
The UK side gave it up in April version.


5. Keynes’s Stance

Keynes had two aspects – an advocate of internationalism as a planner and a defender of the interests of the British Empire, and had a tendency to change his stance according as the situation developed.
  In the initial period, Keynes designed and put forward plans filled with the spirit of internationalism for commodity problem, relief and reconstruction problem, and international monetary system, which were considered to be important in constructing the postwar international order. These clearly showed Keynes’s excellence in internationalism as a system planner, albeit they would ensure the interests of the British Empire.
  As the practical political and economic situations proceeded, Keynes came to show an aspect of the pragmatist, among others making it a priority to protecting the interest of the British Empire.
  In the case of commodity problem, he came to advocate the Sixth version (May 1942), giving up the Fifth version [of International Buffer Plan] (April 1942) which was much more advanced in internationalism. Then he put forward proposals which were more retrograde in principle (the Eighth Version, February 1943). Although in September 1943 the plan was discussed with the US, it was rather negatively treated. Moreover, a commodity plan itself failed within the UK due to harsh opposition from the Ministry of Agriculture.
In the case of relief and reconstruction problem, it was in October 1941 when he put forward the Central Relief and Reconstruction Fund Plan. However, as early as February 1942 he came to adopt a pragmatic line mainly dependent on the existing Lend-Lease, giving up the CRRF plan based on internationalism because of an abrupt deterioration of the economic situation of the British Empire.
Then came an international monetary system. Around June 1943 Keynes, in substance, came to put his own International Clearing Union plan aside, and tried
to make some sort of compromise by reforming the White plan through the monetization of unitas. This effort failed because it was not accepted by the US. Then, in the end, Keynes even came to justify the White plan on the ground that it was much more crucial to secure a financial aid from the US – justification difficult to understand from the point of view of the ICU plan.
  As to both commodity plan and relief and reconstruction plan, what Keynes initially aimed at came to be completely foiled at an early stage (February 1942 – February 1943). Under these situations, Keynes might have hoped somehow to establish an international monetary system by accepting the US plan, albeit incomplete.
  Keynes had been much concerned that without the help from the US the British Empire might collapse. It should be noted, in this respect, that he had not a slightest idea of emancipating the colonies (for example, as a strategy which the UK should adopt after the Far East area was liberated, Keynes argued that the problem should be coped with, without resort to Roosevelt for help, through cooperation within the British Empire.
  How could we interpret the changed stance which Keynes showed through these negotiations? This is quite interesting and very difficult to answer.
  Initially he put forward a plan which is, in nature, based on internationalism. If he had been a pure scholar and put forward his own idea from the university or the media, he would have critically argued the process developed in the sphere of international political economy from a point of view of internationalism.
   However, Keynes was not that sort of man. He put himself in the forefront of the reconstruction of international order. He also represented the British Empire, and was situated in the position in which he needed to adjust the whole, looking for some sort of compromise with the US in negotiation. Thus his political stance – of course, much influenced by his own political thought – greatly governed his action, making much sacrifice of his aspect as a scholar and a system designer.   
  Therefore, when considering these problems, we need to think of the fact that we encounter two Keynes – Keynes as an advocate of internationalism and Keynes as a representative of actual political negotiation. When considering the latter aspect, we need to examine in concrete terms how he came to make compromise. Any researcher who are interested in this field is required a cool eye, for Keynes had neither shown nor spoken some sort of compromise through these negotiations.


6Conclusion
  In Reference to Present Significance

The result of the above examination runs as follows.

(1) The negotiation between the UK and the US over an international monetary system started with a face-off of the ICU plan and the SF plan. (Oct.23, 1942. A long discussion between Keynes and White). However, we can say that at an early stage, the initiative was gripped by the US side, as was seen in June 1943 Keynes tried to integrate the two plans based on the White plan. Although the British side made an effort partially to incorporate the feature of the ICU into the White plan by monetizing unitas since September 1943, it finally gave it up in April 1944.

(2) Through these negotiations Keynes played an outstanding role representing the British side. And yet he gave up his own ideal ICU proposal at an early stage, and then tried to monetize unitas but in vain. After that he came to show an aspect of pragmatist who stressed the importance of getting financial aid from the US. What he aimed at was to maintain the position of the British Empire in the postwar world through financial aid from the US, by cooperating with it rather than holding out against it.

The postwar period was to have the IMF system (based on the White plan) as an international monetary system up until 1970. The system sometimes referred to as the Dollar Standard was managed as the fixed exchange system. However, around 1970, there often occurred the Dollar Crisis, which led to the announcement of the Nixon Doctrine. Then around 1973 the world monetary system saw a great transformation into the flexible exchange rate system.
 In 1999 the Euro System was set up in Europe, and a wide area of the advanced region was incorporated into a single monetary zone. At the same time, however, we saw a remarkable economic growth in the emerging nations as represented by the BRICS. Thus in recent years the voices for looking for a new appropriate monetary system to replace the Dollar Standard has become bigger and bigger.
The financial globalization which rapidly proceeded in the 1990s has made foreign exchange markets a target for speculative activities (e.g. G. Solos’ activities). Simutaneously securitized products together with indexed speculation rapidly increased, to say nothing of the activities of the hedge funds. Against these tendencies no government has been able to implement an effective measure up to the present, notwithstanding the devastating financial collapse since the Lehman shock. Markets are still worshipped, whatever type of markets they are, by governments, and the financial circles. 
Given these present globalization (characterized by the rule of the SBS, and the laissez-faire activities of the speculators), how effective the Keynes’s ICU plan would be --- this is a present serious point for consideration.
  It is, truly, a historical problem to investigate how the IMF system was to be set out through a series of negotiations in the 1940s. And yet the original ICU plan has, par excellence, great significance for considering a possible international monetary system. In this respect, we need to pay attention to the EUP which had had some success in the development of European monetary system (in the 1960s). Explicitly based on the Keynes Plan, it was a clearing system among the member nations and had used an equivalent to bancor.)


Appendix: EURO and ICU Compared

How Would Keynes Have Seen?

The EURO system considerably constraints a degree of freedom for the member countries. They abolished their own currencies (so the foreign exchange markets disappeared), leaving monetary and foreign exchange policy to the ECB. Moreover, for the maintenance of fiscal discipline, the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) is ruled. This involves that each member has no means to control and manage its own economy. This is seriously divergent from what Keynes contemplated in the ICU plan.
However, because Euro is a local currency, when viewed from the world as a whole, there exists the foreign exchange market and the flexible exchange system is adopted.
  At present the EURO system sees extreme imbalance among the member nations in terms of the balance of payments, and as a method of tackling this problem, “structural reform” only such as liberalization of labor markets and cuts in wage are implemented. 
  The EURO leaders have met the ongoing crises by resorting to a mixed policy of bail out and austerity measures. What they have aimed at was to stabilize the EURO system (the relief of the financial institutions as well), while imposing increased tax and cut in spending on the countries concerned. As a result of this, the system has barely survived, while the economies of the countries concerned have been worsened up until the present day.
  If the ICU system rather than the EURO system had been implemented, there might not have occurred this kind of problem. Using one example, a big surplus in Germany occurs because of a big deficit in Greece. Because Greece spent much money (which was lent by the German banks), Germany could sell many Benz cars there. Erroneously, however, the ruling view in Germany ascribed Greek crisis to immoral spending.
Above the EURO system, there stands the EU, for there are several members who would hesitate to enter it (the most important country should be the UK). The EU has continued to take a course of expanding its influence with the idea of real politik. Different from the communitarian spirit of the former European Community, it has been moving in the spirit of big powers, which is typically seen
in the move to incorporate the ex Eastern European countries into the NATO. The EU which shows this type of action and the EURO system as a monetary union --- it is a very difficult task to maintain some harmony between the two.
Even if confined to EURO, it has increased in number on a rather ambiguous standard. No one could now say that the system meets Mundel’s Optimum Currency Zone.
It would be an illusion to think that the EURO system can conquer the present crisis through early implementation of the Fiscal Union or Political Union as advocated by Merkel. Europe has many divergent cultures, so even if one tried to make divergence unified, there would appear some crack somewhere. Apart from this, the social fatigue and tension would not allow that sort of unification. There exists a risk of explosion or implosion at any moment.
   EURO system is urgently required to be greatly reformed.

*Emeritus Professor, Sophia University, Tokyo 
 Provisional version not to be quoted. 


1) In working out the construction of the postwar world, it should be a fact worth of paying attention that these fields were conceived in a closely linked way in Keynes’s mind. On this point we should not neglect the role which Harrod and Mead played.
2) Moreover, the Gold Standard had become, in substance, the de-facto Dollar Standard after the First World War.
3) In passing, the postwar Cambridge had an atmosphere in which Robertson and Meade would be driven to a corner by J. Robinson. And it also had Sraffa. When we consider the postwar Cambridge, it is very important to understand these circumstances. We cannot say that there continued to exist a unified school called the Cambridge School (Robbins continued to be the boss of the LSE.).
4) This is quite understandable.
5) Keynes was well known, together with Lytton Strachey, for an excellent description of characters, as is shown in “Isaac Newton” and The Economic Consequence of the Peace.
6) This was a problem in which if India and others which came to possess a huge sum of the UK national debts would sell them after the war is over, the UK would fall into a serious financial crisis. In fact, in 1949 this problem occurred and saw a great fall in pound. India began to sell a huge sum of the British debts, and changed the pounds thus obtained into dollars, which caused the fall in pound. The UK government intervened in the foreign exchange market to support pound by selling dollars. But soon the dollars run out … This was the sterling problem. 
  7) For what proceeded from the Queen Mary (May 1944) to Bretton Woods (March 1946), see Hirai (2014). His activities during this period are characterized by his flexibility, that is, Keynes as a political pragmatist. The principal task of international negotiations, among others, between the US and the UK during this period was to breed the “hybrid” dog – which was born from the SF plan and the ICU plan and agreed in the Joint Statement – in more concrete figure.
                                                                                                     

References                                                             

Amato, M. and Fantacci, L. (2012), The End of Finance. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Bateman, B., Hirai, T., and Marcuzzo, M.C. eds. (2010), The Return to Keynes, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Carabelli, A. and Cedrini, M. (2010), “Current Global Imbalances: Might Keynes Be of Help?” in Bateman, Hirai and Marcuzzo eds.
Carabell, A. and Cedrini, M. (2013), “Some Foreseeable Disasters of the Global Economy: The High Cost of Neglecting Keynes’s Approach” in Hirai, Marcuzzo and Mehrling eds.
Gnos, C. and Rochon, L-P. (2004), “Reforming the International Financial and Monetary System: from Keynes to Davidson and Stiglitz”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, Vol.26, No.4.
Gold, J. (1981), “The Multilateral System of Payments: Keynes, Convertiblity, and the International Monetary Fund’s Articles of Agreement”, International Monetary Fund, August 1981.
Greenwald, B. and Stiglitz, J.E. (2008), A Modest Proposal for International Monetary Reform, International Economic Association Meeting, Istanbul, available at: http://policydialogue.org/files/events/Greenwald_Stiglitz_Modest_Proposal_for_Reform.pdf.
Harrod Papers, Chiba University of Commerce Library.
Hirai, T., M.C. Marcuzzo and Mehrling, P. eds. (2013), Keynesian Reflections, Oxford University Press.
Hirai, T. (2013), “International Design and the British Empire”, History of Economics Review, 55, 2.
Hirai, T. (2011), “Keynes and the Transmutation Process of the Plan for Commodity Control Scheme”, ESHET Conference (Bogazici University, Istanbul), May.
Hirai, T. (2014), “From the Queen Mary to Bretton Woods May 1944 to March 1946(mimeo).
Iwamoto, T. (1999), Keynes and the World Economy, Iwanami.
Keynes, J.M. (1980), Activities 1940-1944 – Shaping the Post-War World: The Clearing Union, Macmillan (CWK, Vol.25).
Keynes, J.M. (1980), Activities 1941-1946 – Shaping the Post-War World: Bretton Woods and Reparations, Macmillan (CWK, Vol.26).
Keynes, J.M. (1980), Activities 1940-1946 – Shaping the Post-War World: Employment and Commodities, Macmillan (CWK, Vol.27).
Keynes, J.M., Correspondence and Memoranda with Roy Harrod, Department of Economics Library, University of Tokyo.
Mikesell, R.F. (1944), The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir, Princeton University.
Moggridge, D. (1992), Maynard Keynes, Routledge.
Skidelsky, R. (2000), John Maynard Keynes Vol.3 Fighting for Britain, 1937-1946, Macmillan.
Spahn, P. (2013), “In a Keynesian Mood?: Why Exchange Rate Systems Collapse” in Hirai, Marcuzzo and Mehrling eds.
Trautwein, H-M. (2010), “A Return to Macroeconomic Policy: A Return to Active Stabilization?” in Bateman, Hirai and Marcuzzo eds.
Wray, R. (2013), “Financial Keynesianism and Market Instability”, in Hirai, Marcuzzo and Mehrling eds.

Related Documents Held by the National Archives, UK

International Clearing Union:
International Stabilising Fund:
Bretton Woods:
John Maynard Keynes: