2013/07/26

HES, Puget Sound, USA June 2005 HOW DID WICKSELL’S THEORY OF CUMULATIVE PROCESS

HES, Puget Sound, USA

 June 2005


HOW DID WICKSELL’S THEORY OF CUMULATIVE PROCESSINFLUENCE KEYNES AND HIS CONTEMPORARIES?
*
                                
Toshiaki Hirai



I.         INTRODUCTION

  Monetary economics came to the fore with Wicksell (1898), a century after Thornton (1802).1 The theory of cumulative process proposed by Wicksell was to have great influence on economic theory in the 1920s-30s through critical interpretations.
The purpose of the present paper is to examine this strand of thought by taking in Keynes, Myrdal and Hayek as well as Wicksell. How did Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process influence them? How did they evaluate Wicksell’s theory as monetary economics, and in so doing take a critical stance on the neoclassical orthodoxy? To what degree did they accept and criticize Wicksell’s theory? What precisely are their theories? And what are the similarities and differences between them?
To borrow from Robbins (1955, 58-59), “[w]hat is relevant in this connection” is not “whether [their theories] followed [Wicksell] in all respects but whether [they] conformed to the type of analysis of which [Wicksell’s theory is] the archetype”.2 We should also pay attention to Robertson’s (1933, 99) correct remark: “… if it is true that differences of terminology sometimes overlie similarity of analysis, it is also true that similarity of practical prescription sometimes overlies divergence of analysis. It is these artificial logomachies and artificial alliances which make it so difficult to assess just what degree of synthesis has been achieved and just where the crucial elements of unresolved controversy still lie” [Here Robertson bears Keynes’s theory and Hayek’s theory in mind].
We will address these questions, which are of fundamental importance to: (i) understand how monetary economics developed in the inter-war period (one of the most significant developments in modern economics); (ii) understand how Keynes accepted and then rejected Wicksell’s influence, or to trace out the Keynesian Revolution; (iii) understand recent developments in monetary economics.3


II.       INTERPRETATIONS OF WICKSELL’S INFLUENCE

A considerable number of studies have to date appeared on the evaluation and influences of Wicksell’s theory. Here we will review them, classify them in their various categories, and then go on to declare our stance reached on the basis of our own examination.  

1. Diverse Assessments of Wicksell’s Influence

A. Positive Evaluation
We shall begin with the scholars evaluating Wicksell’s influence positively, although for different reasons.
Leijonhufvud (1981) points to a maladjustment of the rates of interest as the core of Wicksell’s influence, taking the essence of the Keynesian Revolution as either “the Treatise plus the quantity adjustment” or “the General Theory minus the theory of liquidity preference” (so called the “Z theory”).4 In other words, he supports the loanable funds theory, rejecting the theory of liquidity preference as a theory of interest, and the “dual decision hypothesis” as a theory of effective demand. From this viewpoint he criticizes the “Neoclassical Synthesis”.
 Shackle (1967, Chapter 9) takes Wicksell’s influence as working against the general equilibrium theory although his definition is too broad in scope. He regards both the Treatise and the General Theory as manifestations of Wicksell’s influence, both the General Theory and Myrdal (1939) as “one and the same theory” (1967, 126. Hession (1984, 287) follows Schackle), and both the Treatise and Hayek (1930) as two sides of the same coin.
Akashi (1988, 28-29) defines the “Wicksellian Paradigm” as consisting of the real system and a theory of cumulative process, seeing it as casting doubt on the quantity theory of money and yet still keeping the remnants of the classical dichotomy. In the line of succession to the paradigm he saw, on the one hand, Hayek, bringing the focus on the process of real fluctuations, and, on the other hand, the Stockholm School (Lindahl and Myrdal) and the Cambridge School (Robertson and Keynes), with the focus on the process of monetary fluctuations. Akashi (1988, 202-204) logically explains the “Keynesian Paradigm” in terms of the IS-LM formula.
Hishiyama (1990; 1993) sees Wicksell’s cumulative process theory as a challenge against the classical dichotomy and the quantity theory of money, and as a denial of the capacity of the rate of interest to adjust the economy. The Treatise, in contrast with the General Theory, is regarded as exemplifying the “Wicksellian mode of adjustment”.
Chiodi (1991, 39) rates Wicksell’s theory against Ricardo’s classical (and neoclassical) monetary theory while, in the same text (Chapter 8), seeing the younger generation as set on the wrong path. Examining Lindahl and Ohlin, Chiodi (1991, Chapter 8) takes a somewhat critical position on the concept of the Wicksell’s influence. He also maintains that Wicksell’s monetary theory has been so far misinterpreted, criticizing Patinkin and Leijonhufvud. Maintaining that Wicksell’s theory is coherently critical of the quantity theory, Chiodi (1991, 1) describes Wicksell’s attitude toward the quantity theory as “schizophrenia”.
Laidler (1991, 119) agrees with an observation made by Ohlin in 1936 in regarding Wicksell’s theory as “an amplification” of the old quantity theory (Gootzeit (1999), Ebeling (1999), Humphrey (1999), and Ascheim=Tavlas (1999) share this view), recognizing that Wicksell’s followers rejected the quantity theory. Laidler focuses on Wicksell’s softening attitude towards the quantity theory between Wicksell (1898) and Wicksell (1915), from which he concludes that Wicksell was a persistent exponent of the quantity theory.
The Horizontalists and Circuitists such as Graziani (2003) and Rochon (1999) rate Wicksell’s influence highly solely in terms of money endogeneity or a circuit point of view.5 They reject the theory of cumulative process and the loanable fund theory as Wicksell’s influence, accepting the Treatise while tempted to reject the General Theory (especially the theory of liquidity preference).

B. Negative Evaluation
Let us now go on to the scholars who view Wicksell’s influence negatively.
  Milgate (1982, 76) and Garegnani (Eatwell=Milgate, 1983, Chapter 7) criticize Wicksell’s influences, arguing that Wicksell’s theory [inclusive of Hawtrey (1913; 1923), Robertson (1926) and Lavington (1922)] marks the “embellishment” rather than overthrow of neo-classical economics.
Amadeo (in Davis, 1994) regards the Wicksellian analysis found in Lindahl, Hayek and others as the “sequence of static finite periods” method, as opposed to Keynes’s “dynamic equilibrium method”.
Rogers (1989) criticizes Wicksell’s monetary theory as no more than an extended version of the quantity theory of money pertaining to “real analysis” which is in sharp contrast with long-term “monetary equilibrium” as expressed in chapter 17 of the General Theory (genuine “monetary economics”). His concern is exclusively with Wicksell, paying little attention to other Wicksellians such as Myrdal, Hayek and others.

C. Our Stance
Wicksell accepted the classical dichotomy, and the Walrasian general equilibrium theory as a theory of relative prices. However, he rejected the quantity theory of money as a theory of absolute prices, and instead put forward a theory of cumulative process.
The leading young economists, whose theories will be examined in this paper below, were greatly influenced by Wicksell’s theory. The largest contribution which they made to economic theory lay in proposing their own brand of monetary economics through immanent criticism of Wicksell’s theoretical system. Among others, Myrdal and Hayek explicitly criticized Wicksell’s acceptance of the classical dichotomy and the Walrasian general equilibrium theory, and endorsed Wicksell’s criticism of the quantity theory of money. And they endeavored to construct new monetary economics through immanent criticism of Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process.
As for Keynes, he was not aware of the classical dichotomy and the Walrasian general equilibrium theory, clearly endorsing Wicksell’s criticism of the quantity theory of money, and endeavoring to construct a new monetary economics taking Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process into account.
We value Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process because it enabled Myrdal, Hayek and Keynes to abandon the quantity theory of money, and opened the way for them to construct their own brand of monetary economics, advancing somewhat further than Wicksell himself. It should be noted that their theories incorporate fluctuations in both prices and quantities, in contrast with Wicksell’s theory which only considers fluctuations in prices under the assumption of full employment.
So far, therefore, we have advanced a positive evaluation of Wicksell’s influence as greatly contributing to the emergence of the new monetary economics. However, Wicksell’s influence sharply decreased thereafter, for Keynes was to develop his theory of employment as seen in the General Theory independently of Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process. In our view, there exist two types of theories in the Treatise: ‘Keynes’s own theory’ and a Wicksellian theory. The former is more important than the latter, for Keynes abandoned the latter soon after the Treatise. Furthermore we see the General Theory taking a markedly critical position on Wicksell’s influence. We value the General Theory for putting forward a theory of employment as a new brand of monetary economics, criticizing the classical dichotomy, and the quantity theory of money - a new version of monetary economics departing from the monetary economics that persisted under Wicksell’s influence.
In order to illustrate our stance as outlined above, we will examine Wicksell, Keynes, Myrdal, and Hayek in terms of their own views and theoriew, thereby showing to what serious ends they criticized the classical dichotomy and the quantity theory.


III. WICKSELL

1.   Wicksell’s View of the State of Economics

On the one hand Wicksell is a neoclassical economist who argues that a successful economic theory should comprise a theory of relative prices and one of absolute prices, the two being separable. On the other hand, he holds that the theory of absolute prices has serious flaws.6
  On the theory of relative prices, Wicksell (1893) regards Walras’ general equilibrium theory as accurately describing the system of production, distribution and exchange, except its capital theory.7
As for the theory of absolute prices, Wicksell (1898) sees the quantity theory as erroneous and puts forward his theory of cumulative process.8
Wicksell criticizes the quantity theory on three points:

(i) It assumes the constancy of the velocity of money: in fact, it fluctuates greatly in the actual economy, and is theoretically unlimited.
(ii) It assumes that the medium of exchange consists of notes and coins only, so that the quantity of money is inelastic if the quantity of currency remains constant. In fact, numerous instruments of credit are used, so that the quantity of money is elastic. This is especially true of an “organized credit economy”.
(iii) It holds that an increase in the quantity of money induces an increase in money prices and a fall in the money rate of interest. In fact it accompanies a rise in the money rate.9

2. Wicksell’s Theory of Cumulative Process10
  Wicksell’s theory11 explains changes in money prices in terms of the relation between the natural rate and the money rates of interest. The quantity of money is assumed to adjust to changes in money prices and trade.12
The natural rate of interest is defined as “the rate of interest which would be determined by supply and demand if no use were made of money and all lending were effected in the form of real capital goods” (Wicksell, 1898, 102). It fluctuates incessantly due to technical progress, belonging to the theory of relative prices. Any change in the natural rate triggers a change in the price level. Wicksell (1898, 119) states that the market rate of interest “usually follows … [the natural rate] very slowly and with considerable hesitation”

  Wicksell supposes that the banking system has no rapid access to information on changes in the natural rate while industry has. He also assumes that it can lend out money at a certain rate of interest whatever the demand for money might be.
Thus the divergence between the natural rate of interest and the market rate can persist over an appreciable period. It is only as a result of the movement of prices that the two rates of interest become equal.

  Suppose that in an organized credit economy the market rate of interest is kept lower than the natural rate for a certain period of time. The entrepreneurs borrow money from the banking system, using it as a “wage-rent” fund, and advance it to laborers, landlords and so forth, who, in turn, purchase consumption goods from the capitalists by spending their income. The capitalists earn interest by depositing the sale proceeds which they made at the beginning of the period. The entrepreneurs engaged in production in the current period sell their output (consumption goods) to the capitalists, and repay borrowed money to the banking system. As a result, the entrepreneurs obtain excess profits equal to [the natural rate - the market rate] × advanced capital.
  If the entrepreneurs continue to reap excess profits, their desire to expand production grows (no actual expansion occurs, the structure of roundabout production being assumed to remain constant). The demand for labor, raw materials, durable investment goods and so forth increases, which induces rises in money wages and rent (full employment is assumed). The entrepreneurs need to borrow more money from the banking system. This is advanced to laborers and landlords, and the same process as above proceeds.
  Once the entrepreneurs conduct their business taking rising prices into account, prices rise at an accelerated pace due to the “law of continuity and inertia” (Wicksell, 1898, 135). Eventually this process comes to an end as the market rate of interest catches up with the natural rate with the stability of prices at a new equilibrium.
  At the root of the theory of cumulative process lies the determination of the price level of consumption goods by aggregate supply and aggregate demand. Aggregate supply is assumed to remain constant while aggregate demand depends on the entrepreneurs’ willingness to expand production.
  With regard to the argument that incomes determine the price level of consumption goods, Wicksell refers to the first half of Tooke’s thirteenth proposition.13

We may formulate Wicksell’s theory as follows:

           Dt = Dt t-1)                     (1)
          Mt = Dt                          (2)
          πt-1 = Dt-1·(n - r)                  (3)
          Ct-1= Dt-1·r                        (4)
           St = Yt-1 - (πt-1 + Ct-1)/Pt-1          (5)
          Dt = Pt·St                         (6)
           Y = Yt-1 = ft-1(T)= constant        (7)
where D is the amount of money required by entrepreneurs, π excess profit, M the amount of money supplied by the banks, Y the volume of output of consumption goods, f(·) the production function, n the natural rate of interest, r the money rate, C the amount of money obtained by capitalists, S the supply of consumption goods, P the price level of consumption goods, and time.

  Here n and r are exogenous variables, Dt-1 and Pt-1 predetermined variables. The system contains six endogenous variables (Dt, πt-1, Mt, St, Ct-1, Pt) and six equations, so it is soluble.

  Entrepreneurs determine how much money is required based on πt-1 ((1)). This amount of money is financed by the banking system ((2)). πt-1 is equal to the amount of money required in the previous period (advanced capital) multiplied by the difference between the two rates of interest ( (3)). The amount owed in interest in the preceding period is equal to the money rate multiplied by the amount of money required in the previous period (((4)). The amount of consumption goods supplied in this period, St, is equal to Yt-1 minus the sum of the volume consumed by entrepreneurs, πt-1/Pt-1, and the volume consumed by capitalists, Ct-1/Pt-1 ((5)). The price level of consumption goods, Pt, is determined by aggregate demand, Dt, and aggregate supply, St ((6)).14 The volume of output remains constant ((7)).
  From equations (5) and (6) the following equation is obtained:

Dt = Pt [Yt-1 - (πt-1 + Ct-1)/Pt-1]     (8)

  The left-hand side is the demand of the factors of production for consumption goods, while the expression in square brackets on the right-hand side represents the supply of consumption goods to the factors of production. The price level is determined by these two. This should be the ‘fundamental equation’.
  From equations (3), (4) and (7), the following is obtained:

Pt = Dt/[Y - Dt-1·n/Pt-1]          (9)

  Thus, in the case where, in the previous period, the rate of the demand for money required by entrepreneurs is either larger than (Wicksell probably had this case in mind), or equal to, the rate of increase (decrease) in the price level, the price level necessarily goes on rising (falling) so long as the demand for money required goes on increasing over time.







IV. KEYNES AND HIS CONTEMPORARIES

1. The Treatise15

A. Keynes’s View of the State of Bank Rate Theories
  We shall examine Keynes’s views on bank rate theories, investment/saving and the quantity theory of money.

  Keynes identifies four bank rate theories so far developed, variously regarding the bank rate as;

(i) the means of regulating the quantity of bank money. Keynes thinks something essential is missing there.
(ii) the means of protecting a countrys gold reserves. Keynes evaluates and uses it in his open system.
(iii) a psychological influence on price levels. Keynes criticizes this for a failure to explain the original effect of the change in the bank rate on the price level.
(iv) influencing investment and savings: Keynes regards this as the essence of the bank rate. He sees Wicksell(1898) as representing this idea and coming close to his fundamental equation16:

  Although the bank rate plays a pivotal role in Keynes’s theory, money supply also has a part to play. This may have something to do with Wicksell’s construction of his theory in an organized credit economy, and Keynes’s criticism that Wicksell does not succeed in linking up his theory of bank rate to the quantity equation (TM.1, 167).
  Keynes explains his “general theory of bank rate” as an extension of (iv) as follows:

(i) Suppose that the market rate of interest, say, rises above the natural rate, which causes the demand price of investment goods to fall (Profit Deflation), resulting in a decrease of the volume of investment. A rise in the market rate of interest also causes savings to increase, though not by an equal amount. Thus investment decreases more than savings increase.
(ii) A fall in the price level of investment goods causes production to decrease (which means a decrease in the value of investment). In addition, since an increase in savings means a decrease in consumption, the price level of consumption goods decreases.  Thus, the price level as a whole falls.
(iii) When producers incur losses, they cut the level of employment at the existing rate of earnings. If this continues, unemployment increases until the rate of earnings is reduced (Cost Deflation. TM.1, 171).

  Keynes argues (i) with the second fundamental equation in mind. The first point in (ii) is based on the TM supply function (to be explained later) in the investment goods sector, the second on the first fundamental equation.
  Here the second fundamental equation occupies a central position, and the first fundamental equation a relatively minor one. The two equations and the TM supply function are used here somewhat loosely.17

  Keynes stresses that investment is not usually equal to savings, offering two reasons: those who determine the division of the total output are not the same as those who determine that of the total income; earnings and savings do not include entrepreneurs’ profits (or losses), while the value of investment does.

  Keynes criticizes the quantity theory18 as follows:

(i) It deals with the various kinds of ambiguous price levels;
(ii)It fails to distinguish between income, business, and savings deposits, so that disturbances arising from changes in the relative proportions of deposits cannot be explained.
(iii) It cannot analyze a dynamic process in which the price level changes from a divergence between saving and investment.

  Underlying his criticism is an important conviction: unless the influence of the bank rate upon investment and saving and the distinction between earnings and profits are introduced into analysis, the dynamic process of price formation cannot be captured. He arrives at this conviction, claiming an advantage of the “fundamental equations over the quantity theories (see TM.1, 198-199); any analysis which fails to distinguish between various kinds of transactions will cause confusion.
 Keynes offers two reasons for giving priority to the bank rate over the quantity of money.19
 
(i) A change in the bank rate influences various factors such as the volume of output and the rate of profits, which means that we cannot estimate the quantity of money related to any one of them.
(ii) The direction of causation is as follows: changes in the bank rate cause the market rate of interest to shift relative to the natural rate, which in turn causes the quantity of money, and consequently the price level, to move.

B. Keynes’s Theory in the Treatise20
a. Two Theories
The most significant feature of the Treatise theory should be the coexistence of a Wicksellian theory and ‘Keynes’s own theory’.
  The Treatise belongs to Wicksellian strand of thought in explaining the fluctuations of the economy in terms of the natural and money rates of interest, and accepting Wicksell’s three conditions of monetary equilibrium.
  At the same time, Keynes develops his own theory, consisting of two parts, one of which addresses the determination of variables relating to consumption goods and investment goods in ‘each period’.

(Mechanism 1) The cost of production and the volume of output are determined at the beginning of the current period. Once the expenditure for consumption goods is determined on the basis of earnings, it is automatically realized as the sale proceeds of consumption goods, and the price level and the profit amount are simultaneously determined.

(Mechanism 2) The cost of production and the volume of output are determined at the beginning of the current period. The price level of investment goods is determined21 either in the stock market or as the demand price of capital goods. As a result, profit is determined.

  The other part deals with the determination of variables between one period and the next.

 (Mechanism 3) The behavior of entrepreneurs is such that, if they make a profit (loss) in the current period, they expand (contract) output in the next.

  We will refer to this behavioral function as the TM supply function.
  Now, ‘Keynes’s own theory’ can be expressed as the dynamic process consisting of Mechanisms 1 and 2 working through Mechanism 3 --- a dynamic process inclusive of price levels and volumes of output.

  b. The Credit Cycle
  The Treatise depicts the credit cycle as follows. Suppose that something (a new invention, say, or a return of business confidence) happens to increase the attractiveness of investment. The price level of investment goods rises, and their output increases in the next period through the TM supply function. As a result, the level of employment and consumption increase. Consequently the price level of consumption goods rises, and their output increases in the next period through the TM supply function. Thus the behavior of firms in increasing output under high profit causes a rise in money wages (“income inflation”). In this process, the volume of working capital also increases, so that business continues to pick up at an accelerated rate.
  The turning point occurs as a result of several causes: evaporation of the attractions of new investment; faltering in financial expectations (due to the predominance of bearishness, and an increase in the financial circulation); a fall in the price level of consumption goods (due to the slower increase in the expenditure on consumption than in the output of consumption goods, as well as the growing inability of the banking system to keep pace with the increasing requirements of the industrial and the financial circulations, which incidentally causes a rise in the rate of interest.
  Then the economy tends to decline for a number of reasons: a fall in the price level of consumption goods drives away entrepreneurs whose production costs are high; financial sentiment becomes bearish; and an increase in the requirements of the industrial circulation causes a rise in the rate of interest and retards investment. Keynes considers the fall in the price level of consumption goods in this phase to be appreciably large. Shortly thereafter, together with a decrease in working capital, production decreases through the TM supply function, so that business deteriorates rapidly.
  The economy is now at the lowest level. It moves toward the upper phase again due to the following causes: the price level of consumption goods stops falling, and begins to rise because consumption decreases less than output, and liquid capital increases. Together with the restored attractiveness of new investment, these cause the economy to pick up again.

After the Treatise Keynes went on applying ‘Keynes’s own theory’, disregarding Wicksellian theory. The ‘The Monetary Theory of Production’ manuscript in mid 1932 (JMK.13, pp.381-396) is a typical example of this approach. Subsequently Keynes proposed a simultaneous equation system in a manuscript entitled ‘The Parameters of a Monetary Economy’, written at the end of 1932 and marking a turning point in the path leading up to the General Theory.22 For detailed discussion of these points see Hirai (1997-1999): suffice it here for me to point out that the Wicksellian way of thinking left no trace or influence on Keynes’s theoretical development after the Treatise.

2. The General Theory
  Interestingly enough, the General Theory rejects Wicksell’s cumulative process theory. Keynes stresses the need to allow for interaction in the way the economy works, and equality of saving and investment (see GT, pp.84, 85).
  Keynes criticizes two related ideas, namely the notion that credit creation by the banking system makes investment possible without any corresponding saving, and the theory of forced saving. In the case of the latter, he argues that it has no meaning unless some “standard rate of saving” is defined, and this is defined on the assumption of full-employment.
  Keynes, is, furthermore, critical of Wicksell’s natural rate of interest (see GT, p. 243) as well as of a cumulative method, favoring an interactive method.

3. Myrdal

A. Myrdal’s View of the State of Economics
Myrdal took his criticism of neoclassical orthodoxy further than Wicksell. He noted the then growing dissatisfaction over the lack of internal integration between price theory and monetary theory in Walrasian theory23, where the problem of production and exchange is dealt with as a theory of relative prices, while the quantity theory is used as an appendix for the determination of absolute prices.
  How did orthodox economics come to incorporate a sharp division between the two theories? Myrdal describes neoclassical marginal utility theory as overthrowing the classical production cost theory with the result that money came to be regarded as merely representing the power to purchase goods and services.
  He deems closer integration of the quantity theory with general price theory to be logically impossible, for they are based on different principles.24
  Even if the integration were indeed impossible, would some co-ordination be possible? Myrdal argues that attempts made in this direction are fraught with difficulty.25 Unlike price theory, which can remain at an abstract level, the quantity theory cannot help contacting with the real world.
The quantity theory thus developed, he argues, has serious defects26:

(i) During a dynamic process the velocity of money varies, which rules out any simple relation between the quantity of money and the price level.
(ii) The relation between the quantity of money and the price level cannot be one-way, for both simultaneously depend on factors outside the mechanism of payment proper.
(iii) The price level in the theory cannot be defined in the form of providing the multiplicative factor required by the theory of relative prices.
(iv) Although the quantity theory stresses movements of the price level, no homogeneous price level exists. It ignores the change within the price level.
(v) The price level merging in the theory is a curious concept including the prices of pecuniary rights.
(vi) The quantity theory challenges practical possibility by adopting total sales as weighting principle of a price index.

  Points (i) and (ii) are made by Wicksell. However, points (iii) and (iv) are not, for the autonomy of relative prices is taken for granted in the case of Wicksell.

  Myrdal goes on to criticize the central price theory:27

(i) Failing to provide the “multiplicative factors”, the price theory remains abstract and unreal.
(ii) The theory has prices relating to a single point in time, so that the price theory cannot treat time contracts. Thus the problem of credit is relegated to the quantity theory, which in turn proves unfit for the task, dealing only with the price level. Credit is crucial not only to the price level but also to price relations.
(iii) Because the price theory embodies Say’s Law, it cannot analyze business cycles.

  In the credit problem Myrdal pinpoints a serious defect brought into economics by the separation of monetary theory from the price theory.

B. Myrdal’s Own Theory
a. Basic Theory
  Mrydal endeavored to construct his own monetary theory through careful examination of Wicksell’s “monetary equilibrium”, for which the three conditions are: (i) equality between the market rate of interest and the natural rate; (ii) equality between investment and saving; and (iii) price level stability.28
  Wicksell considered them to be equivalent only as assumptions. Myrdal’s conclusion is:

(1) What matters to monetary equilibrium is condition (ii).
(2) Condition (i) does not hold good. But the argument based on condition (i) implicitly contains an investment function which is important in the theory of cumulative process.
  (3) Condition (iii) does not hold good.

  Myrdal formulates monetary equilibrium in which condition (ii) holds good as follows:

           R2 = W = S + D            (1)
where R2 is the production cost of gross investment, W free capital disposal, S savings proper, and D total anticipated value-change of the real capital. All are expressed in ex-ante terms. The money rate of interest which satisfies (1) is “normal”.29
                  
  R2 is the discounted value anticipated at the initial point of time, which the entrepreneurs calculate by discounting various kinds of cost needed for a certain amount of investment. It is a money demand for new investment.
  The amount of money which the public are free to dispose of is expressed in ex-ante terms. Savings proper (hereafter savings) are defined as the part of income not used for consumption goods.30
                                                                   
               Y - C = S           (2)
where Y is income, C consumption, and S saving.

  Income, which is synonymous with “net return”, is an ex-ante concept defined as:

Y = B - (M + D)      (3)
where B is the discounted sum of all anticipations of gross returns in the next period, M the discounted sum of all anticipations of gross cost in the form of operating cost of the co-operating means of production in the same period.

  Gross investment and free capital disposal are both ex-ante concepts determined by different economic agents, and thus not equal. They are, however, ex-post equal, for the banking system makes up for the difference.
  Myrdal’s monetary equilibrium has two characteristics: a position departure from which produces a cumulative movement, and the fact that it fixes certain specific price relations. Myrdal considers that in monetary equilibrium relative prices, the price level, and production might change.

  Now suppose that the economy starts off in monetary equilibrium.
 The investment function works as the driving force. This is given by:

R2 = F (Q)          (4)
where F(.) is the investment function, and Q the profit margin.

  This shows that the entrepreneurs as a whole determine the amount of investment based on the profit margin.
  Q is given by:

              Q = Σ w (c1- r1)   (5)31

where c1 and r1 are, respectively, the value and the reproduction cost of the existing real capital, and w the investment-reaction coefficient of each firm’s investment function.

  Equation (5) says that the profit margin as a whole is the sum of the profit margin of individual firms, which is the difference between the value and the reproduction cost of the existing real capital possessed by each firm, weighted by w. Myrdal assumes that the value of capital fluctuates violently while the reproduction cost is inflexible because it includes various kinds of inflexible prices.
 
Let us now turn to consumption goods. Here we find two kinds of argument.
The first is concerned with determination of the price level of consumption goods. The part of income not saved is always equal to the volume of consumption goods sold, O, multiplied by its price level, P1:

             Y - S = P1.O          (6)

  The left-hand side is the demand for consumption goods, C, which is an ex-ante concept. The volume of production is determined ex-post by the roundabout production structure. The price level of consumption goods is determined here.

  Equations (2) - (6) complete the system. This holds good in each period. Income and the profit margin are subjectively expected concepts. The entrepreneurs determine the amount of investment based on the profit margin. The amount of investment is realized in accordance with Wicksell’s assumption of “freie Valuta”. The amount of investment thus realized is injected into the stage of production of intermediate goods. The demand for consumption goods ascertained through equation (2) determines the price level together with the volume of production ascertained through the roundabout production mechanism.
 
The second argument centers on the idea that a rise (fall) in the price level of consumption goods induces, through its effect on expectations, a rise (fall) in the value of capital, C1, in the next period. This is expressed as:

          ΔC1 = Φ (ΔP1)    (8)

  This influences the profit margin through equation (5). Myrdal’s model is thus completed as a dynamic system.
  We need to note here how Myrdal deals with the natural rate of interest and the money rate. He argues that in a system inclusive of money and credit the natural rate of interest should be redefined as a rate of return of planned investment, and that the difference between the two can be understood as the difference between the existing capital and the reproduction cost. Thus the difference between the two rates is incorporated in Myrdal’s model in the redefined form. Believing as he did that even in monetary equilibrium there exists a profit margin which stimulates investment, he rejected Wicksell’s first condition that is, zero profit margin cannot be a criterion of monetary equilibrium in dynamic conditions.32 Thus Myrdal was able to evade a semi-dichotomy into which Wicksell fell.
 
b. The Cumulative Process
  Based on the above system, Myrdal explains the cumulative process in three cases in which a primary change occurs: (i) a change in anticipations; (ii) a change in the money rate of interest; (iii) a change in savings. What is explained is the situation in which divergence between investment and free capital disposal is cumulatively expanding, due to the primary change.

  Suppose that some primary change takes place in an economy in which monetary equilibrium has been attained. The initial impulse then induces a change in the value of real capital, while it does not induce any change in the cost of production, so that the profit margin changes, in turn bringing about a change in the demand for investment. At the same time, the initial impulse induces a change in income through a change in “total anticipated value-change of the real capital”, which in turn leads to a change in saving or consumption ((i) and (ii). In (iii) saving directly changes without a change in income). As a result of all this, change also occurs in free capital disposal.
Due to the above process, monetary equilibrium is not maintained and the economy begins to move in either direction. Free capital disposal is money capital provided voluntarily by the public. The difference between the demand for investment and saving is provided by the banking system (the assumption of “freie Valuta”). This is a sort of forced saving.

 A change in the demand for investment goods and for consumption goods induces a change in the roundabout production structure, which, in turn, gives rise to a change in the volume of production of both goods.
 Change is then brought about in the price level of consumption goods and in anticipations. The former change is related to equation (6), the latter to equation (8) an important factor in making economic fluctuations cumulative.

3. Hayek

A. Hayek’s View of the State of Monetary Theory
  Hayek classifies the development of monetary theory in four stages, arguing the need to attain the fourth stage. Hayek (1931, 4-5) criticizes the quantity theory as the first stage from the point of view of methodological individualism, arguing that aggregate concepts such as the quantity of money, the general price level, and the amount of production can have no influence on the decision-making of individuals.
  Even when quantity theorists refer to relative prices, Hayek (1931, 6-7) argues, changes in them are attributed to “disturbing factors”.
  Hayek criticizes the quantity theory on the grounds that even when it discusses the influences of prices upon production, it does so only in terms of the general price level and total production.33

  Hayek is also dissatisfied with the neoclassical system per se, arguing that monetary theory is by virtue of the quantity theory detached from general economic theory34, which means a theory of relative prices.

  Hayek objects to the classical dichotomy. He rejects the theoretical validity of the quantity theory from the standpoint of methodological individualism and criticizes the general economic theory on the grounds that it ignores the effects of money.35

B. Hayek’s Own Theory
  Hayek advocates a monetary theory that analyzes the process by which a change in the quantity of money influences the structure of roundabout production through a change in relative prices.36
  Hayek considers his theory to be built on Wicksell’s theory, eliminating its defects37 along the correct line developed by Mises (1912).38
  Hayek’s theory of roundabout production runs as follows:

 People spend their money income on consumer goods or producer goods; The relative prices of these goods change depending on whether relative demand for each kind of good increases or decreases. As there are various kinds of producer goods, changes in relative prices cover consumer goods and various kinds of producer goods. Thus there occurs a change in the price margin between successive stages of production; producer goods, consisting of both non-specific and specific goods, shift so as to be used in higher (lower) stages of production; the structure of production becomes longer (shorter); and the volume of output of consumer goods increases (decreases).39

  Hayek applies this analysis to two states of the economy, taking the cases of “voluntary saving”40 and “forced saving”. The demarcation is whether the quantity and velocity of money remain constant and do not influence the real economy.
  The former characterizes the normal state of the economy which the monetary authority should aim at, while the latter represents its disruption, prolonging disequilibrium.

Let us see what happens in the case of forced saving.
  When additional money is injected into an economy which is initially in a state of equilibrium, how are natural or normal prices disturbed and how is the structure of production affected? Two cases can be distinguished: (i) the new money (credit) is provided to producers, who desire to obtain producer goods; or (ii) the new money (credit) is provided to consumers, who want to buy consumer goods.

  In case (i), investment (the demand for producer goods) is equal to the sum of voluntary saving and new credit. In case (ii), investment is equal to voluntary saving. In either case, the amount of money increases due to the provision of credit, resulting in the money rate of interest falling below the natural rate. Crucially, case (ii) follows as a result of case (i) having occurred. Let us begin with case (i).

  Would-be entrepreneurs provided with credit can now purchase producer goods, but only if they offer to pay prices higher than do the existing entrepreneurs. Due to the fall in the money rate of interest, a rise in the price of the original means of production, and a rise in the prices of non-specific producer goods, the existing entrepreneurs will find it rational to reduce expenditure on the original means of production and increase expenditure on new intermediate products (capital).
  Thus the new entrepreneurs can generate a new, more roundabout stage of production in the economy through obtaining the necessary original means of production and non-specific producer goods. In this way the production process comes to be drawn out.

  The volume of output in the stage of production, from which the original means of production and non-specific producer goods were withdrawn and directed toward a higher stage of production, decreases. Because of this, the volume of output of consumer goods will also decrease over time. This is “forced saving” in Hayek’s sense. Due to the decrease in the production of consumer goods and the invariable consumption expenditure, the prices of consumer goods rise. Hayek believes consumers would like to restore their real consumption to its former level, if possible, by spending more money. The money income of laborers working in the producer goods sector increases, because more money is handed over to the entrepreneurs in this sector. The laborers are able to spend their extra money income on more consumption. Thus the laborers increase their expenditure on consumption while the volume of output of consumer goods does not increase so quickly. As a result, the prices of consumer goods rise further and further.
  This argument is crucial to Hayek’s theory. The lengthening of the roundabout production structure must eventually increase the output of consumer goods. However, it is theorized that in the case of forced saving no actual increase occurs. The increased expenditure on consumption due to the increased income of the laborers also plays an important role in Hayek’s theory. The output of consumer goods will temporarily decrease due to the lengthening of the roundabout production structure, while expenditure on consumption will continue to increase.
As a result, the prices of consumer goods go on rising cumulatively. This is the cumulative process in Hayek’s sense.

  As a result of the public’s increasing its expenditure on consumption out of increased income, with the hope of making real consumption return to its former level, there eventually occurs a reverse in the movement of the ratio of demand for consumer goods to demand for producer goods, so that the prices of consumer goods rise relative to those of producer goods.

  In this step we see the origins of case (ii). The reverse movement of the ratio of demand for consumer goods to demand for producer goods is the same as case (ii), in which the economy moves in the opposite direction from that in case (i). However, Hayek points out the following differences which explain why in case (ii) a serious depression takes place: (a) the emergence of an excessively short roundabout production structure; (b) specific producer goods are relatively abundant, and their prices fall. 

  It should be noted that in Hayek’s theory the prices of consumer goods and non-specific producer goods go on rising in the depression phase. It is only the prices of specific producer goods that fall. It should also be noted that unemployment occurs because the adjustment required in the shortening of the roundabout production structure does not occur smoothly. Accordingly, depression in Hayek’s sense is frictional in nature.
  Hayek goes on to advocate that the production structure should be adjusted in accordance with the ratio of voluntary saving to voluntary spending as quickly as possible, and that arbitrary injections of money should be avoided as they disturb this normal ratio and push the economy into crisis (see 1931, 95).


V. SIMILARITIES AND DIFFERENCES

Having completed our examination of the stances and theories of Wicksell, Keynes, Hayek and Myrdal, the first point we wish to stress  is that each has its own peculiar features, and indeed the latter three are independent of Wicksell.
Wicksell’s theory centers around the two rates of interest. In Keynes it is his “own theory” that matters. Myrdal’s theory is based on investment and free capital disposal (saving), with the emphasis on ex-ante and ex-post concepts. Hayek’s theory centers around the theory of roundabout production with the emphasis on voluntary and forced savings.
Having established these points, we also wish to stress that Keynes, Hayek and Myrdal are greatly influenced by Wicksell. All of them evaluate Wicksell’s theory highly in the evolution of monetary economics, and regard their theories as pertaining to Wicksell’s line of thought.

In the following paragraphs we shall see how Wicksell, Keynes, Hayek and Myrdal relates to one another in terms of degrees of similarities and differences adding Lindahl and Mises.
Wicksell, Keynes, Hayek, Myrdal and Mises adopt period analysis which aims at analyzing transitional periods, while Lindahl analyzes disequilibrium given that equilibrium is attained at each period.
Wicksell, Myrdal, Lindahl and Mises41 assume an organized credit economy. Keynes does not adopt this line, although the emphasis in his analysis falls on the bank rate rather than the quantity of money. What matters to Hayek is whether the quantity of money is kept constant.
  Wicksell, Keynes, Hayek and Mises adopt a ‘divergence between the natural and money rates of interest’ as an analytical tool, but in different ways. In Wicksell this tool occupies a central place. In Keynes the focus is set rather on the relation between the rate of interest and investment/saving. In Mises and Hayek the money rate of interest is uniquely defined as the price of consumers’ goods over that of producers’ goods.42 Myrdal and Lindahl are critical of this tool. Myrdal argues that monetary equilibrium cannot be defined as equilibrium of the two rates of interest. Lindahl argues that at each period the value of investment is determined in such a way that the two rates of interest are equal.
Myrdal and Keynes adopt a divergence between investment and saving as an analytical tool, arguing that it can be traced back to Wicksell. Hayek assumes that investment is always equal to saving. What matters to him is the distinction between voluntary saving and forced saving. Lindahl assumes that at each period investment becomes equal to saving.
Wicksell, Myrdal, Lindahl, Mises and Hayek adopt a theory of roundabout production. Mises and Hayek regard it as crucial in monetary economics, while Wicksell, Myrdal and Lindal do not. Only Keynes does not adopt it.
Wicksell, Myrdal, Keynes and Mises approve the concept of the price level. Mises accepts it in the form of “internal objective value of exchange” of money, although he is somewhat reluctant to calculate the index number. Only Hayek rejects it from a methodological point of view.
  What matters to Wicksell are the fluctuations in money prices while the others consider the fluctuations in relative prices. Mises and Hayek link the fluctuations in relative prices with a theory of roundabout production. Myrdal and Lindahl develop a similar argument, albeit not as a central place.
Wicksell assumes full employment or constancy of the volume of output43 while the others consider fluctuations in the volume of output. Myrdal argues that the theory of relative prices, which takes Say’s law for granted, cannot be applied to analyze the problem of the business cycle.
Wicksell, Lindahl, Myrdal and Keynes regard the expenditure from income as crucial in determining the price level of consumers’ goods.
Wicksell adopts wage fund doctrine while the others do not.
Wicksell, Keynes and Lindahl stress the importance of the stability of the price level through bank rate operations while Myrdal and Hayek are critical of this view.
Hayek explicitly develops a doctrine of forced saving, stating that it is developed in Wicksell and Mises. Keynes is critical of it, arguing that it has nothing to do with the main argument of a theory of money.


VI. CONCLUSION

Wicksell put forward a theory of cumulative process as an alternative to the quantity theory of money. It is a theory of how the fluctuations in the price level are caused by the divergence between the natural rate and money rate of interest in the organized credit economy. Wicksell took for granted the classical dichotomy between the theory of exchange value and the theory of money prices.
  Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process greatly influenced younger economists, who succeeded to Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process through their immanent criticism. They did not, however, accept the dichotomy, arguing that monetary theory should not be confined to the determination of absolute prices only.
As far as the above is concerned, it was shared by them. They concurred both in rejecting the above dichotomy and in their reasons for doing so. However, they differed in how and on what points they should or should not accept Wicksell’s cumulative process theory. Their aim was to construct their own monetary theories, criticizing neo-classical orthodoxy.
In the case of Myrdal, a divergence between investment and saving (free capital disposal) induces a change in the roundabout production structure, which brings about a change in the prices of consumption goods and expectations; this, in turn, widens divergence between investment and saving. It should be noted that Myrdal reached his investment theory through his critical examination of the natural rate and market rate of interest.
In the case of Hayek, what matters is the case of forced saving which takes place through injection of money. Although the effects differ according as to whether money is injected into the investment goods or consumption goods sector, analysis of the roundabout production proves the sovereign approach.
In the case of Keynes, in light of the fact that the three conditions for monetary equilibrium are accepted and the second fundamental equation is used mainly in the applied part of the Treatise, Wicksell’s cumulative process theory seems to be accepted most faithfully. However, what matters in the Treatise should be not so much this point as ‘Keynes’s own theory’.
In the present paper we have endeavored to clarify Wicksell’s influence through examination of the views advanced by economists on the state of economics at their time and reconstruction of their theories, exploring their similarities and differences.
Keynes shows partial acceptance of Wicksell’s cumulative process theory in the Treatise. Theoretically speaking, however, this is not a crucial point. When we trace his theoretical development from the Treatise onward, it is essential to keep the main focus on how he dealt with ‘Keynes’s own theory’. It was through his self-critical reflection on this that he eventually arrived at the General Theory. His harsh criticism of the Wicksellian way of thinking to be seen in the General Theory epitomizes the nature of the painstaking journey that he labored on for five years.



NOTES


1) Wicksell (1889, p.514 in Boianovsky=Trautwein (2001)) ascribes his theory of cumulative process to Ricardo (1810). For comparison with Wicksell (1898), see Boianovsky=Trautwein (2001). Wicksell (1898) does not refer to Thornton. The similarity was pointed out in 1916 by Davidson to Wicksell. See Laidler (1991, 150).
2) The original refers to Ricardo.                   
3) See, for example, Moore (1988), Rogers (1989) and Woodford (2003).
4) For a criticism of the “Z” theory from a point of stock equilibrium and “own rates of interest”, see Cottrell and Lawlor (1991).
5) Realfonzo (1998) characterizes Wicksell’s influences as “monetary theory of production” critical of “neoclassical theory”. We make much the same point in this paper.
  6) On which see Chiodi (1991, 48-50). The difference between Wicksell and Mises is examined in Bellofiore (2000, 549-554) in great detail.
  7) For the difference between Wicksellian and Walrasian general equilibrium theory, see, for example, Rogers (1989, Chapter 2).
  8) See IP, 135. For the debates about Wicksell’s cumulative process theory --- among Wicksell, Davidson and Åkerman --- which took place in Sweden in early 20th century, and which influenced Lindahl’s and Myrdal’s monetary economics in the 1920s and 1930s, see Siven (1998). Wicksell (1913) is a rejoinder to Davidson.
  9) On which, see IP, 165-167. Keynes labeled it as the “Gibson Paradox”.
  10) Wicksell (1915) does not consider that the fluctuations in prices occur due to a divergence between investment and saving. It is not the money rate of interest, but the natural rate of interest which is determined by an equilibrium of investment and saving. He maintains that the fluctuation in prices occurs due to a divergence between the natural rate of interest and the money rate of interest.
  11) Ahiakpor (1999) regards Wicksell’s theory of cumulative process as retrogession. His commentators, Gootzeit, Ebeling, Humphrey, and Aschheim=Tavlas oppose Ahiakpor’s view. My understanding is close to Humphrey’s. I do not, however, concur with the view shared by the four that Wicksell’s theory is an extended and elaborate version of the quantity theory of money. This is partly due to their wider definition of the quantity theory of money.
  12) Stressing the “supply of deposits” rather than “real shocks and rate differentials”, Humphrey (1997) regards Wicksell as “a bona fide quantity theorist”. I would say the reverse is true, for the “supply of deposits” is passively determined in Wicksell’s theory.
  13) See Wicksell (1898, 44). This is accepted by Lindahl (1939, 142), Myrdal (1939, 22), and the Treatise (1, 122).
 14) This is in accord with Siven’s (1998, p.131) view in relation to “excess demand or interest gap as an engine of inflation”.
  15) We regard Hawtrey (1913) and Robertson (1926) as pertaining to the Wicksellian stream of thought, although they do not undergo Wicksell’s direct influence.
16) See TM.1, 176-177. Kahn (1984, 74) denies Wickell’s influence on the Treatise.
  17) This is true of the argument at TM.1, 183-187.
  18) See TM.1, 205. We identify three types of interpretation: The Treatise accepts it; The Treatise criticizes it; and The Treatise stands in between.
  19) See TM.1, 196-197. This shows why the Treatise regards money supply as endogenous. For exogeneity/endogeneity in Keynes’s economics, see Moore (1988) and Graziani (2003).
 20) For details, see Hirai (1997-9, pp.88-104).
 21) Hicks (1935) discovers three theories of money: savings and investment theory; a Wicksellian natural rate theory; the bearishness function in the Treatise.
He finds the third one most interesting.
 22) See Hirai (2004).
 23) See Myrdal (1939, 10-11).
24) See Myrdal (1939, 11-12). 
25) See Myrdal (1939, 13).
  26) See Myrdal (1939, 14-15).
  27) See Myrdal (1939, 16-17).
  28) Wicksell (1908) stresses the importance of the stabilization of the price level. This caused controversy with Davidson who thinks of the relation between an increase in productivity and the fall in the price level. Robertson’s (1928, 56-57) argument concerning the relation between economic growth and the fall in the price level runs along Davidson.
29) See Myrdal (1939, 96).
30) See Myrdal (1939, 90). Y is not used in the original.
  31) See Myrdal (1939, 79). In the original, cand r are written as c and r1 respectively.
  32) See Myrdal (1939, 83-84).
  33) See Hayek (1931, 6-7).
  34) See Hayek (1931, 3-4).
35) Mises (1912) argues that the quantity theory fails to explain variations in the value of money in terms of subjective valuation (See 91-92). This criticism goes in tandem with that of the classical dichotomy.
  36) See Hayek (1931, 28).
  37) See Hayek (1931, 26).
38) See Hayek (1931, 25-26)PP, 25-26. For the relation among Wicksell, Hayek and Mises, see Bellofiore (1998).
  39) Expenditure on consumer goods is assumed to increase more rapidly than their production.
  40) See Hayek (1931, 50-54, 55-57, and 75-79).
  41) This aspect of Mises is emphasized as an “ultra-Wicksellian idea” by Bellofiore (1998). For Mises’ criticism of Wicksell, see Mises (1912, 355-357), and Wicksell’s reply (1914).
  42) This definition is criticized by the General Theory (192) as well as by Hawtrey (1935).
  43) “The Great Depression” in the fourth quarter of the 19th century saw a gradual fall in prices together with full employment. Wickesell’s theory reflects this. It was not until the early 1920s that he became concerned with a change in output and employment. See Boianovsky (1998).



REFERENCES


Ahiakpor, J., “Wicksell on the Classical Theories of Money, Credit, Interest and the Price Level: Progress or Retrogression?”, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 58-3, 1999, pp. 435-86, which includes comments by Aschheim, J.=Tavlas, G., Ebeling, R., Humphrey, T., and Gootzeit, M.
Akashi, S. The Genealogy of Macroeconomics, Toyo Keizai Shinpousha, 1988 (in Japanese).
Amadeo, E., “Changes in Output in Keynes’s Treatise on Money” in Davis, J. ed., 1994.
Amadeo, E., “The Wicksell-Keynes Connection”, Australian Economic Papers, December 1994.
Aoyama, H., Theories of Economic Fluctuations of the Cambridge School and the Stockholm School, Sobunsha, 1953 (in Japanese).
Bellofiore, R., Between Wicksell and Hayek: Mises’ Theory of Money and Credit revisited, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, v. 57 no.4, 1998, pp. 531-78
Boianovsky, M., “Wicksell on Deflation in the Early 1920s”, History of Political Economy, 30-2, 1998, pp. 219-75.  Boianovsky, M. and Trautwein, H., “An Early Manuscript by Knut Wicksell on the Bank Rate of Interest”. History of Political Economy,  33-3, 2001, pp. 485-516.
Chiodi, G., Wicksells Monetary Theory, Macmillan, 1991.
 Cottrell, Allin; Lawlor, Michael S.,Natural Rate’ Mutations”. History of Political Economy, 23, 1991, pp. 625-43.
Davis, J. ed., The State of Interpretation of Keynes, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1994.
Deutscher, P., R.G. Hawtrey and the Development of Macroeconomics, Macmillan, 1990.
Eatwell, J. and Milgate, M. eds., Keynes’s Economics and the Theory of Value and Distribution, Duckworth, 1983.
Graziani, A., The Monetary Theory of Production, Cambridge UniversityPress, 2003.
Hawtrey, R., Good and Bad Trade, Constable and Co., 1913.
Hawtrey, R., “A Review of Mises (1935)”, Economic Journal, XLV, 1935, 509-518.
Hayek, F., Prices and Production, Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1931.
 
Hession, C., John Maynard Keynes, Macmillan, 1984.
 
Hicks, J., “A Suggestion for Simplifying the Theory of Money”, Economica, February 1935.

Hirai, T. “The Wicksell Connection I-II”, Sophia Economic Review, Vol.36, No.1-2, 1990 (in Japanese).
Hirai, T. December 1997 – March 1999. “A Study of Keynes’s Economics (I) - (IV)”, Sophia Economic Review.
Hirai, T. “The Turning Point in Keynes’s Theoretical Development, History of Economic Ideas, XII, 2, Dec. 2004.
Hishiyama, I., From Quesnay to Sraffa, Nagoya University Press, 1990 (in Japanese).
  Hishiyama, I., A Modern Evaluation of the Economics of Sraffa, University of Kyoto Press, 1993 (in Japanese).
Humphrey, T., “Fisher and Wicksell on the Quantity Theory”, Economic Quarterly (Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond), 1997, 83-4.
Keynes, J.M., A Treatise on Money I.II, Macmillan, 1930 (TM, I and TM.2 are used for quotations).
Keynes, J.M., The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Macmillan, 1936.
Laidler, D., The Golden Age of the Quantity Theory, Philip Allan, 1991.
Laidler, D., Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution, Cambridge University Press, 1999.
Milgate, M., Capital and Employment, Academic Press, 1982.
Mises, L., The Theory of Money & Credit, Harcourt Brace & Co., 1935 (translated from the German, 1912, by Batson, H.)
Moore, B., Horizontalists and Verticalists, Cambridge University Press, 1988.
O’Brien, D. and Presley, J. eds., Pioneers of Modern Economics in Britain, Macmillan, 1981.
Latsis, S. ed., Method and Appraisal in Economics, Cambridge University Press, 1976.
Lavington, F., The English Capital Market, Methuen, 1922.
Leijonhufvud, A., Information and Coordination, Oxford University Press, 1981.
Lindahl, E., Studies in the Theory of Money and Capital, George Allen and Unwin, 1939 (1930).
Mises, L., The Theory of Money & Credit, Harcourt Brace & Co., 1939 (1912, 1924[second]).
Myrdal, G., Monetary Equilibrium, W. Hodge, 1939.
Realfonzo, R., Money and Banking, Edward Elgar, 1998.
Ricardo, D., The High Price of Bullion, 1810 in Sraffa, P. ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, Vol.3, Cambridge University Press, 1951.
Robbins, L., “Schumpeter on the History of Economic Analysis,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, LXIX I, 1955.
Robertson, D., Banking Policy and the Price Level, Staples Press Limited, 1926.
Robertson, D., “Theories of  Banking Policy”, Economica, June 1928 (in Robertson, pp.39-59).
Robertson, D., “The Future of Trade Cycle Theory”, 1933 (in Robertson, pp.98-103).
Robertson, D., Essays in Monetary Theory, Staple Press Limited, 1940.     .
Rochon, L-P, Credit, Money and Production, Edward Elgar, 1999.
  Rogers, C., Money, Interest, and Capital, Cambridge University Press, 1989.
Sandelin, B. ed., Knut Wicksell Selected Essays in Economics, Vol.II, Routledge, 1999.
Schackle, G., The Years of High Theory, Cambridge University Press, 1967.
Siven, C., “Two Early Swedish Debates about Wicksell’s Cumulative Process”, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 5-1, 120-139, 1998.
Suzuki, R., The Stockholm School, Senbundo, 1976 (in Japanese).
Thornton, H., An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain, George Allen & Unwin, 1939 (1802).
Wicksell, K., Value, Capital and Rent, George Allen and Unwin, 1954 (1893).
Wicksell, K., Interest and Prices, Macmillan, 1936 (1898).
Wicksell, K., Lectures on Political Economy, Vol.2 Money, 1915 (1906. Translated from the second Swedish edition by Classen, E.).
Wicksell, K., “Stabilizing the Value of Money ─ A Means of Preventing Crises”, Ekonomisk Tidscrift, 1908 (in Sandelin ed., 1999, 32-39).
Wicksell, K., “The Regulation of the Value of Money”, Ekonomisk Tidscrift,1913 (in Sandelin, 1999, 46-52).
Wicksell, K., “Review” of Mises (1912), Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung, XXIII (1-2), 144-149, 1914.
Woodford, M., Interest and Prices, Princeton University Press, 2003.







*The paper originates in Hirai (1997-1999, Chapter 3). The earlier versions were read at Prof. M. C. Marcuzzo’s workshop on 14 September 2004 (University of Rome “La Sapienza”), and the International Conference on the Cambridge School of Economics on 26-27 February 2005 (Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo). I appreciate valuable comments by Profs. R. Backhouse (Univ. of Birmingham), M. Boianovsky (Univ. of Brazilia), P. Groenewegen (Univ. of Sydney), O. Hamouda (Univ. of York), B. Ingrao (Univ. of Rome), N. Naldi (Univ. of Rome), S. Nisticò (Univ. of Cassino), A. Roncaglia (Univ. of Rome), and Dr. E. Sanfilippo (Univ. of Rome).
Faculty of Economics, Sophia University, Tokyo. E-mail:hirai-t@sophia.ac.jp