April 2007
AN ANALYSIS OF THE GENERAL
THEORY PROOFING
PROCESS
―
From “The Pre-First Proof Typescript” [Summer 1934] to the General Theory ―
I. Introduction
The main purpose
of this paper is to examine and to show, objectively and exactly, how Keynes carried
out the proofing process of the General
Theory, and is to detect its main features. The period covers the summer in
1934 to February 1936.
The key points in this paper are as follows:
There exists no paper which has examined the
latter half of Keynes’s developmental process from the Treatise to the General
Theory in spite of the fact that many studies on the Keynesian Revolution
from a point of history of economic thought have been so far made. The reason
is that almost all the studies have been concentrated on the period up to
1933-34, maintaining that the Keynesian Revolution or the General Theory has been, in substance, completed in 1933 (albeit
this is right), and that little effort has been spent for clarifying the eighteen
months leading up to the General Theory.
What
concerns us in this paper are: what are the major changes in this proofing
process?; How and why did Keynes make changes, after having made a drastic
change from the Treatise to the road
to the General Theory up by 1933?
In
order to answer these questions, we need to investigate the following.
1)
To
endeavor to describe accurately, based on the material concerned, how Keynes
made changes.
2)
To
consider the implication and significance which these changes brought about to
Keynes’s theory.
The first task is descriptive and explanatory, while
the second one is theoretical in nature. Through the second task, we may shed
some light on the nature and characteristics of the General Theory. (It may not be, for example, a complete book in
terms of theory.)
During the period concerned, Keynes handed in his
manuscript piecemeal, rewriting incessantly. Retracing this process might
reveal the significant changes in the final stage. Keynes sent the galley
proofs to his colleagues for their comments. The correspondence concerned will highlight
the differences between them in theory.
Keynes had constructed many
of the major components of the General Theory (including the theory of
liquidity preference, the marginal efficiency of capital, the fundamental
psychological law, and the multiplier) before the time of “The General Theory”.
However, in terms of style it is in “The General Theory” that we first find
material that was actually incorporated into the General Theory. For
example, Ch. 12, “The State of Long-Term Expectation (or Confidence)”, of “The
General Theory” was very much the prototype for Ch.12, “The State of Long-Term
Expectation”, of the General Theory. Similarly, Ch.10, “The Propensity
to Spend”, of “The General Theory” is the precursor of Ch.8, “The Propensity to
Consume: I. The Objective Factors”, and Ch.9, “The Propensity to Consume: II.
The Subjective Factors”, of the General Theory.
As mentioned in Section 5 of Ch.6, Keynes
remarked in his letter to Kitoh of 22 June 1934 that “it will be some months
more before I am ready for printing”. This should be compared with the fact
that he had completed almost all the text outlined in the table of contents of “The
General Theory” by March 1934, went to the United States in May and came home
in June, as we saw in Section 1 of Ch.10. To illuminate the succeeding phases
of the proofing process in chronological order, which are to lead up to the
publication of the General Theory —
that is the purpose of this paper.
During the eighteen months
or so from summer 1934 to February 1936, Keynes submitted the manuscript to his
publisher in installments, and revised the galley proofs several times. In
fact, he continued to modify the expression of his ideas all through this period
right up to publication.
A reconstruction of the proofing process
illuminates the gestation of the General Theory. There are two main
reasons for this. First, Keynes adopted the somewhat unusual procedure of
handing in his manuscript piecemeal rather than in one go, rewriting constantly
as he went along. Retracing this process gives us considerable insight into the
significant changes he introduced along the way. In this context it should be
remembered that although the consumption theory, the investment theory, and the
theory of liquidity preference had all virtually reached their final forms by
spring 1934, the theory of effective demand and the definitions of some
fundamental concepts - such as user cost - had yet to be finalised. Second,
Keynes sent the corrected galley proofs to several close colleagues for their
reactions. The correspondence this generated highlights the differences between
Keynes's theory and the theories of these colleagues very clearly, as well as
the features they had in common. The picture is somewhat complicated, however,
because the debates concerning points of disagreement Keynes had with Robertson
and Hawtrey had begun prior to the Treatise and continued into the
period of the General Theory, with no clear line of demarcation between
the discussions of the one book and those of the other.
In this paper we will
examine the developmental process of the General Theory dividing it into
two phases. One is the period from the Pre-First Proof Typescript (summer 1934)
up to Galley1(III) (to be explained below. June-July 1935). The other is the
period after that up until the publication of the General Theory.
Concerning the first period
it is worth noting the following points in advance. First, the First Galley,
which will be explained below, is the most telling of the galleys for our
purpose. There are two reasons for this: (i) the galley is written in line with
the Galley Table of Contents (to be called “TOC” below), which leads us to
suppose that the First Galley laid the foundations for succeeding galleys; (ii)
by examining the appendix to Volume 14 of JMK, entitled “Variorum of
Drafts of the General Theory”(JMK. 14, pp. 351-512; hereafter
referred to as the “Variorum”), we can confirm that in the Second and Third
Galleys (to be explained below) Keynes for the most part made only formal
revisions, though there were a few exceptions to this. It will therefore be
convenient for us to deal with these when we come to discuss the First Galley.
Second, we need to compare and contrast the
developments in this particular set of galleys not only with Keynes’s
economic-theoretical development prior to their production, but also with the
theory presented in the corresponding parts of the General Theory. For
the first set of comparisons we focus on the new ideas each set of galleys
contains. For the second set of comparisons, in addition to the new ideas found
in each set of galleys, we will also examine more formal aspects of the text,
such as the degree of completion, as this will assist us in clarifying in
concrete terms the degree to which Keynes changed and did not change his theory
in the process.
In Section II we will examine “The Pre-first Proof Typescript”, and in Sections
III-VIII we will go on to examine “Galley 1”, “Galley 2” and “Galley 3” (to be
explained below).
Concerning the period after that up until the publication of
the General Theory, through an
explanation of this period, Section X “The Great Revision” and Section XI “The
1935 Michaelmas Lectures” are responsible for it. Section XII is our
conclusion.
II. “The Pre-First Proof Typescript”
A
typescript named “The Pre-First Proof Typescript” (hereafter “Typescript”)
was written in the summer of 1934. It can be divided into two parts.
The first
part consists of Ch.4, “The Choice of Units”, Ch.5, “Expectation as Determining
Output and Employment”1, and Ch.9, “The Marginal Efficiency of
Capital”. They are identical to Chs.4, 5, and 11 of GT, respectively, in both form and title.
The second is Ch.6, “The Meaning of Income”. It differs considerably in
form from the corresponding part of GT.
After some changes in Galley1(I), small formal changes ensued until Galley3,
and in “The Great Revision” it was revised in form.
That summer Kahn helped Keynes. In early September Keynes
wrote to Daniel Macmillan, his publisher: “I am now fairly well on with my
forthcoming [book] … My provisional title is The General Theory of Employment,
Interest and Money.”2
Here we will
examine the Typescript. The employment function and the definitions of some
fundamental concepts merit particular attention.
1. The Employment Function
The following quotation, which deals with the employment function, represents
the origin of GT, Ch.4 (IV), although
different in substance:
We can substitute for the supply function what we shall call the
employment function. The employment function for a given firm (and similarly
for a given industry or for industry as a whole) is given by N = F (Dw),
where Dw is the sale proceeds in terms of wage units, the
expectation of which will induce a level of employment N. Similarly we can
write (Dw/N) = Q(N), which relates the money proceeds per wage unit
to the quantity of employment, so that if N men produce an output O, (Dw/O)
= Q(O) is the ordinary supply curve (JMK.14, p. 387).
Keynes’s intention might have been as follows. The employment function N
= F(Dw) can be reformulated as
Dw = f(N)
(1)
By dividing equation (1) by N, we obtain the equation:
Dw/N
= f(N)/N = Q(N) (2)
Let us express the production
function as
O = g(N) (3)
Then, from equations (2) and (3) the following equation can be obtained:
Dw/O = N・Q(N)/O = g-1(O)・Q (g-1(O))/O
= Q′(O)3 (4)
Keynes calls this the “ordinary supply curve”. Here he seems to be considering
the inverse of the employment function.
On the one hand, the employment function is a supply concept, for it is
considered to be a substitute for the “supply function”. On the other, it is of
the same type as the employment function in “The Summer Manuscript”. Therefore,
N = F(Dw) may also be considered an equilibrium concept.
So much can
be verified with two considerations.
Firstly,
Keynes frequently changed the employment function formulation: (i) in “The
General Theory” as Dw = F(N); (ii) in “The Summer Manuscript”, “The
Typescript” and Galley1(I) as its inverse function; (iii) in Galleys2 and 3 as Dw
= F(N); (iv) in the GT as its
inverse function.
Secondly, the role which the aggregate supply
function plays in the GT was assumed
by the employment function, denoted by either Dw or D, until the GT,
in which D is replaced by Z (aggregate supply price), while D now
denotes effective demand. This likewise indicates that both the employment
function and the aggregate supply function have the attributes of an
equilibrium concept as well as those of a supply concept. Thus, there is some
apparent difficulty in deriving the “ordinary supply curve” from the employment
function.
Compared with this difficulty, the derivation of “the
ordinary supply curve” is of little importance. Suffice it to point out that:
(i) unlike the other galleys, Galley1(I)
does not use the production function;
(ii) from Galley1(I) up to the GT the “ordinary supply curve” describes a relation between the
level of employment and the price level, so that it is not a supply curve in
the ordinary sense.
2. Some Fundamental Concepts
Keynes discusses fundamental concepts such as income, investment,
saving, and effective demand in Chapter 6.
The chapter,
taking over Ch.8, “Investment and Saving”, of “The General Theory” and “The
Summer Manuscript”, forms the basis for fundamental concepts in the period from
“The Pre-First Proof Typescript” to Galley3.
In Galley1(I) Keynes inserts Ch.7, “The Definitions of Quasi-Rent,
Saving and Investment”. The material is utilized somewhat dispersively in GT, Ch.6, “The Definition of Income,
Saving and Investment”. We will therefore defer discussion of fundamental
concepts until Section IX, simply observing here that Ch.6 of “The Pre-First
Proof Typescript” is more relevant to Ch.6 of the GT than the galleys from Galley1(I) to Galley3.
III. Galleys 1, 2 and 3
After “The Pre-First Proof Typescript” came a set of
galleys, which we will call Galley 1, 2 and 3 (see Table 11-1).
(i)
Three galleys
have the same table of contents, which we will call the TOC4.
(ii)
Galley2 is a
revised version of Galley1 while Galley3 revises Galley2. In each galley, only
part of the material specified in the TOC was written. Moreover, Galley2
rewrites only parts of Galley1, while Galley3 rewrites only parts of Galley2. Consequently,
some sections of the text remained at either Galley1 or 2 stage until what we will
call “The Changeover” (September 1935).
(iii)
The text of
Galley1 was, of course, written first, but it appeared in various periods: (i)
early December – mid January 1935 (Galley1(I)); (ii) March - May 1935
(Galley1(II)); (iii) June - July 1935 (Galley1(III)), so parts of Galley1
postdate Galley2.
(iv) Gally1(I) laid the
foundations for succeeding galleys;
(v) On the evidence of the appendix to JMK.14 (pp. 351-512; hereafter “The
Variorum”) we see that in Galleys2 and 3 Keynes made only formal revisions.
(vi) Although Galley1 of GT, Ch.17, “The Psychological and Social
Incentives to Liquidity”, and Ch.19, “The Essential Properties of Interest and
Money” have not survived, we have confirmation that they existed in Robertson’s
letter to Keynes (3 February 1935) 5etc.
We will compare these sets of galleys with both the preceding
developments and the General Theory.
IV. Galley1 (I) (Chapters 1-19)
On 7 September 1934 Keynes announced his publication
programme to the Macmillan Co. and by 13 September 1934 he sent off the first
three chapters (that is, Book I), the titles of which are the same as those of
the corresponding chapters in the GT (although
Ch.3, “The Principle of Effective Demand”, differs in substance). The galley of
these chapters came out in October. Keynes delivered his Michaelmas lectures based
on this galley together with the manuscript for Chapters 4-14.
That Keynes felt this manuscript needed revising is revealed
in two letters to Kahn (18 and 27 September) 6:
Table 11-1 The
Proofing Process
of
TOC
|
Galley1( I) *
[TOC]
|
Galley2
[TOC]
|
Galley 1(II)
[TOC]
|
Galley3
[TOC]
|
Galley1(III)
[TOC]
|
||||||||
1
|
|
|
|
H (the end of January 1935)
|
|
|
|
||||||
2-3
|
|
R
|
|
(the end of January 1935)
|
|
|
H
(June 1935)
|
|
|||||
4-6
|
|||||||||||||
7-14
|
|
H
(the end of
April 1935)
|
|
||||||||||
15-19
|
|
|
|
|
|||||||||
20-25
|
|
|
|
H**
|
|
|
|||||||
26-28
|
|
|
|
|
|
(June - July 1935)
|
|||||||
(Notes) 1. R: the galleys
sent to Robertson.
H: the galleys sent
to Harrod , Hawtrey, Kahn and J. Robinson.
2. The dates in
parentheses indicate the period in which the galleys concerned came out.
3. *: the period
between early December 1934 and mid-January 1935.
**: the period from
March 1935 on. Chs.21-24 with the date of 7-17 May 1935.
I … have found out one or two interesting novelties.
… I’ve solved the riddle of how to define Income in some sort of a net sense….
The deduction from the gross sales proceeds of the output of a given equipment
necessary to yield income is that part of the quasi-rent … necessary to induce
the entrepreneur not to leave his equipment idle. … the sacrifice involved in
using the equipment as compared with postponing its use ….
I am getting towards the end of the re-writing which
you led me into and will show you the new way for dealing with net income in
detail next term.
These progress reports relate to Ch.6, “The Meaning
of Income”, which treats user cost, and Ch.7, “The Definitions of Quasi-Rent,
Saving and Investment”, of the TOC.
Keynes sent the publisher first Chs.4-11, and secondly Chs.12-19 (which respectively
correspond to GT, Chs. 4-9 and Chs.
11-17). Their galleys probably appeared between early December 1934 and
mid-January 1935. They mark the virtual birth of the General Theory. Keynes
sent to Robertson7 Chs.1-19, which we will call “Galley1(I)”.
Let us examine Galley1(I). It can be divided into two parts: Chs.10 and
11 for consumption, and Chs.14-19 for the rate of interest (The chapters to
which we refer below, unless otherwise noted, are those in the TOC).
A. Consumption
Ch.10, “The Propensity to Spend” covers the area of GT, Ch.8, Sections II and III.
Section III,
which discusses the fundamental psychological law, shows hardly any change from
Galley1(I)8 onward.
However, Section II considerably differs from Galley1(I).
“The General Theory” had identified the objective
factors as:
(i) the
quantity of employment as determining the aggregate current rate of real
income;
(ii) the rate of interest;
(iii) the
state of long-term expectation.
Galley1(I) deletes
(i), keeping (ii) and (iii). It discusses (i) separately, using income rather
than the quantity of employment9 (the GT added an argument justifying this substitution).10
Item (ii) is kept
in “The General Theory”, and is included in GT’s
fourth objective factor, “changes in the rate of time-discounting”11.
Item (iii) is also kept in “The General Theory”, and is incorporated to some
extent in GT’s third objective
factor, “windfall changes in capital-values not allowed for in calculating net
income”.
Ch.11 corresponds to GT’s Ch.9,
“The Propensity to Consume: II. The Subjective Factors”. “The General Theory” had
regarded financial provision as a subjective factor, but neither Galley1(I) nor
the GT followed this line.
The argument concerning
the influence of distribution on the propensity to consume is a restatement of that
of “The General Theory”, namely that the employment function becomes a 45° straight
line. The GT drops it and takes
income distribution as given.
Concerning “negative
saving”, Galley1(I) adds negative saving by firms and “unemployment relief
financed by borrowing” together with the purchase of annuities and death duties
in “The General Theory”. The GT
refers only to “unemployment relief financed by borrowing”.
Besides these
changes, Ch.11 is essentially the same as GT,
Ch.9.
As far as Chs. 10 and 11 are concerned, there is no
discernible difference between Galley 1(I) and Galley2, aside from minor
changes in wording.
B. The Rate of Interest
Ch.14, “The General Theory of the Rate of Interest” is nearly identical
to GT, Ch.13, in which the core of the theory of interest is articulated.
In other words, Galley1(I) brings the liquidity preference theory to its final
form. Only small revisions are made to Ch. 14 between Galley1(I) and Galley2.
The same is
true of Ch.18, “Sundry Observations on the Nature of Capital”, which
corresponds to GT, Ch.16 (the same
title) (Section II is traceable to “The Second Undated Manuscript” and “The
Typescript”).
Neither Ch.17, “The Psychological and Social Incentives to Liquidity”, nor
Ch.19, “The Essential Properties of Interest and Money”12
(corresponding respectively to GT, Ch.15,
“The Psychological and Business Incentives to Liquidity”, and Ch.17 (the same
title) ) are extant.
However, we have Keynes’s letter to Kahn (15 January
1935)13, and Robertson’s letter to Keynes (3 February)14 attesting
to them.
The letter to Kahn indicates that Keynes rewrote 90
per cent of these chapters. Certainly Chs.17 and 19 of Galley2, are almost identical
to GT, Chs.15 and 17.
Ch.15, “The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest”, and Ch.16, “Notes
on the Rate of Interest in Marshall’s Principles
of Economics, Ricardo’s Principles of
Political Economy, and Elsewhere” correspond, respectively, to GT, Ch.14 (the same title), and its
Appendix (the same title, replacing “Notes” with “Appendix”).
The differences between Galley1(I) and Galley2 are
of very little account.
In the Great
Revision, however, both chapters were considerably rewritten, as is confirmed
by:
(i) Keynes’s letter to Kahn (27 August)15, in which he is thinking
of completely rewriting the chapters on the theory of interest;
(ii) the fact that among the
chapters on the theory of interest, Keynes rewrote these two chapters only.
Keynes rewrote these two chapters under the
impetus following on discussion with Harrod.16
GT’s Ch.14 consists of 11
pages, of which 7 pages (pp. 177-183) were completely rewritten. Nevertheless,
there is no difference of argument between Galley1(I) and the GT. In
both versions he argues that the classical theory of interest assumes full employment,
so that when income changes, the theory can no longer account for the actual
rate of interest.17
A similar relationship is discernible between GT’s Appendix to Ch.14 and Ch.16 of Galley1(I)18. Keynes
completely rewrote four and a half (out of about seven and a half) pages of the
appendix discussing Marshall
= Pigou’s theory of interest (Section I). Yet when Ch.16 of Galley1(I) and the
relevant passages in GT, Ch.14 are
compared, no changes appear to have been made to the argument:
The perplexity which I find in
Marshall’s account … is fundamentally due … to the incursion of the concept ‘interest’,
which belongs to a monetary economy, into a treatise which takes no account of
money (GT, p. 189, and JMK.14, p. 484);
Professor Pigou ... leads us (in
his Economics of Welfare) to infer
that the unit of waiting is the same as the unit of current investment and that
the reward of waiting is quasi-rent, and practically never mentions interest, —
which is as it should be (GT, p. 190, and JMK.14, p. 484).
The theme is common to GT’s Appendix
to Chapter 14 and to Galley1(I)’s Ch.16, apart from two formal points of
difference:
(i) Galley1(I)
argues that Marshall
does not clearly distinguish quasi-rent as a return on assets from interest as
a return on money19, while the GT deletes it;
(ii) Keynes’s criticism of Pigou’s theory of
interest is more extensively developed in the GT, using Pigou(1927;
1933).20
Galley1(I) also has Chs.6-9 (Book II, “Definitions and Ideas”), and Chs.2-3
(Book I, “Introduction”), which will be examined in the next chapter.
V. Galley2
The
revision of First Galley I, i.e., the Second Galley is particularly interesting
from our point of view on account of the fact that Chapter 17, “The
Psychological and Social Incentives to Liquidity”, and Chapter 19, “The
Essential Properties of Interest and Money”, which correspond to GT’s Ch. 15 and 17 respectively, are
both extant. Judging from the fact that the second galleys for Chapters 1-6
were ready on 29 January 1935, it would seem that some of Galley1(I) must have
been revised and returned to the publisher by the end of 1934. The remaining
part of Galley1(I) would then have been revised by the end of January 1935, as
is confirmed by the letter Keynes wrote to Kahn on 15 January21, in which he says:
I have done two more chapters for you …. [T]hey
cover the ground of the philosophical chapter, ninety per cent re-written … concerning
the fundamental characteristics of interest … considerably remodelled.
This
would appear to relate to Chapter 18, “Philosophical Considerations on the
Essential Properties of Capital, Interest and Money”, of “The General Theory”,
suggesting that Keynes reworked this as Chapter 18, “Sundry Observations on the
Nature of Capital”, and Chapter 19, “The Essential Properties of Interest and
Money'” In response, the publisher returned the remainder of the Second Galley,
i.e. Chapters 7-19, to Keynes towards the end of April 1935.
VI. Galley1(II) (Chapters 20-25)
Galley1(II)
consists of Chs.20-25 which exist only in the First Galley: these chapters appear in neither
the Second nor Third Galleys. They correspond to Chapters 18, 20, 10, 19, 21,
and 22 of the General Theory respectively.
Two pieces of evidence
suggest that Keynes probably sent this off to the publisher after the end of
March 1935. Firstly, he announced in his letter to Kahn of 26 March 1935 (JMK.13,
p. 525):
I have
now finished a full-dress critique of the Prof. [Pigou] to go in as an appendix
to the chapter on changes in money wages.
This would indicate that he
had already finished writing “Appendix on Professor Pigou’s Theory of Unemployment ” to Chapter 23, “Changes
in Money Wages”, which corresponds to “Appendix on Prof. Pigou’s Theory of
Unemployment” to Chapter 19, “Changes in Money Wages”, of the General Theory.
Secondly, this manuscript
was sent off for comment to several other economists in June 1935. From these
we deduce that Keynes received the galley in May 1935.
Galley1(II) represents the
final version of the parts of the General Theory to which it
corresponds.
Ch.22, “The Marginal Propensity to
Consume and the Multiplier”, becomes GT,
Ch.10 (same title); Ch.20, “The Equilibrium of the Economic System”, becomes Ch.18,
“The General Theory of Employment Re-stated”; Ch.21, “The Employment Function”,
becomes Ch.20 (same title); Ch.23, “Changes in Money-Wages”, becomes Ch.19
(same title); and Ch.24, “The Theory of Prices” becomes Ch.21 (same title). Ch.25,
“Notes on the Trade Cycle”, does not survive.
The original idea of Ch.22 is traceable to the First Undated Manuscript,
and that of Ch.21 to “The General Theory” and “The Summer Manuscript”.
As will be explained in the next chapter, Ch.3, “The
Principle of Effective Demand”, of Galley1(I) defined the employment function
as D’= F(N) (D’ denotes “the supply price” in the sense of an expectation of
sale proceeds), N the volume of employment). However, Ch.21 of First Galley1(II)
defines it as N = F(D)22 (where D denotes effective demand).
Then, in the Great Revision, Keynes sets about clearing
up the confusion by calling the employment function of Galley1(I) the “aggregate
supply function”, and that of Galley1(II) the employment function.23
He also brings in the concept of the “aggregate demand function” for the first
time, and re-defines effective demand as exclusive of “user cost”.
From this development we can infer that the
employment function, N = F(Dw), of the GT is a function of the equilibrium value, Dw (effective
demand in terms of wage units). This can be verified by examining the
theoretical structure of the GT directly,
which we do in Ch.13.
Ch.23 of Galley1(II) is traceable to:
(i) Keynes’s attack on Pigou (1933) in September 1933, and the
controversy with Robertson24;
(ii) his first lecture of the 1933 Michaelmas Term;
(iii) a letter to Kahn (26 March 1935) to the effect that he has finished
writing an appendix for Pigou’s book.25
Aside from these Chs. 21-23, we find no precursors to Galley1(II).
We see no difference in content between Galley1(II) and the corresponding
parts of the GT. The only exception26 is Section II of Ch.20,
which summarizes the argument in the preceding chapters. It was considerably
rewritten, probably, in the Great Revision.
VII. Galley3
Galley3 (June) comprises Chs.2-6,
which correspond to GT, Chs.2-5 and
part of Chapter 6.
In early June Keynes sent to Harrod, Hawtrey, Kahn,
and Joan Robinson:
(i) Ch.1
of Galley2;
(ii) Chs.7-19 of Galley2, which correspond to GT, some of Ch.6, Ch.7, Section I-IV of
Ch.8, Chs.9-14, Appendix to Ch.14, and Chs.15-17;
(iii) Galley1(II) (Chs.20-25).
To sum up, what they received was
Chs.1-25 of the TOC, corresponding to GT,
Chs.1-22.
According to Keynes’s letter to Macmillan (31 July)27:
(i) he sent the final pages of Galley3 to the
printer;
(ii) he expected the book to
appear in November.
VIII. Galley1(III) (Chapters 26-28)
Galley1(III) contains three chapters of the
TOC. Although the galley is not extant, the chapter titles are known to us;
(i) Ch.26,
“Notes on Mercantilism and the Usury Laws”;
(ii) Ch.27, “Notes on the History
of the Notion of ‘Effective Demand’ ”, and
(iii)Ch.28, “Is an Individualist Economy Capable of Providing Full
Employment?” 28.
Chs.26 and 27 together would correspond to GT, Ch.23, “Notes on Mercantilism, the
Usury Laws, Stamped Money and Theories of Under-Consumption”29 while
Ch.28 to Ch.24, “Concluding Notes on the Social Philosophy towards Which the General Theory Might Lead”.
Keynes’s letter to J. Robinson (3 September) indicates
that they were sent to her, and were still written along the TOC:
I now have … the last three chapters …. The last two chapters are
completely unrevised. Roy [Harrod] strongly objects to chapter 26 as a
tendentious attempt to glorify imbeciles. ... I have been occupied for several
weeks in somewhat re-writing Book I and completely re-writing Book II. In the
case of Book II practically not a word of the version you have read has been
left standing. … I have somewhat modified my definition of user cost (JMK.13,
pp. 650-651).
On the evidence of this letter together with the galleys he sent to some
fellow-economists in June 1935 and his letter to Daniel Macmillan (11 September)30,
Keynes’s work on these chapters and their appearance in galley form would have
taken place between June and July.
Together with Ch.25 these constitute Book VI, “Short
Notes on Some Applications of the General
Theory”.
As far as the tables of contents are concerned,
these can be traced back to the following:
(i) Ch.17, “Historical
Notes”, of the First Manuscript (1933);
(ii) Ch.20, “Notes on the Trade
Cycle”, Ch.21, “Notes on the History of Cognate Ideas”, of the Third Manuscript
(1933);
(iii) Ch.25, “Notes on
Mercantilism, the Balance of Trade and Foreign Investment”, Ch.26, “Is an
Individualist Economy Capable of Providing Full Employment?”, and Chapter 27, “Notes
on the History of Similar Ideas”, of “The General Theory”.
That Keynes must have produced these chapters in
June or July 1935 is confirmed by the letters to his mother (9 August) 31
and to Harrod (17 August)32. At this point there are three
observations to be made.
First, in his letter to Harrod, Keynes writes:
Chapter 26 is too long …. In chapter 27 the emphasis
hasn’t worked out as I intended ….
Possibly Keynes transferred the substance of Ch.26
to the sections of GT, Ch.23: Sections
I-IV (on Mercantilism); Section V (on the Usury Laws); Section VI (on the
theory of Gesell); (together with the substance of Ch.27) Section VII (on
theories of under-consumption).
Second, we know the origins of some of the ideas in GT, Ch.23. The starting point should be “Historical Retrospect”
(1932)33, which could be connected with Ch.17, “Historical Notes”,
of “The First Manuscript”, which is in favour of:
(i) Mercantilist and Protectionist policies as increasing foreign
investment by improving the balance of trade;
(ii) Anti-usury laws and
principles of cheap-money policies as increasing home investment by lowering
the rate of interest;
(iii) Expenditure as being a thing
in itself “good for trade" by
diminishing the excess of saving over investment.34
“Historical Retrospect” is close to “The Monetary Theory of Production”
in its basic tenor. Also, we have a note concerning Keynes’s 1932 spring
lectures35 which refers to “Mercantilism and Protection”. Keynes
also discusses the seeds of his ideas in his 1932 Michaelmas lecture.
In GT, Ch.23, Section III
Keynes quotes, from Hecksher (1935) several points drawn from various
mercantilist authors as precedents for some of his ideas in GT, which are:
(i) scepticism
about the policy of laissez-faire;
(ii)
the theory of liquidity preference;
(iii)
the need to distinguish between the rate of interest and the marginal
efficiency of capital.
Keynes’s extensive quotation of Hecksher’s text reflects its recent
availability in English. Keynes had an interesting observation to make on
Hecksher and his own position:
Prof. Heckscher is himself an adherent …of the
classical theory and much less sympathetic to the mercantilist theories than I
am. Thus there is no risk that his choice of quotations has been biased … (GT,
p. 341, fn.1).
In GT, Ch.23, VII Keynes
discusses under-consumption theories. Although his line of argument on Malthus
can be traced back to 1922, he did not refer to the relation between
unemployment and effective demand until 1933.
Here Keynes also discusses in detail Mummery=Hobson
(1898), which must date from July 1935, for, writing to Kahn (30 July), he
states:
the book Hobson helped him [Mummery] to write, The Physiology of Industry, is a
wonderful work. I am giving a full account of it … (JMK.13, p. 634).
.
Third, from the letter to his mother (9 August) we are given to
understand that Keynes commenced on Ch.28 in August 193536.
Furthermore, according to the letter to Robinson (3 September)37,
the chapter had by that time been finished. We can infer that Ch.28 became the
basis of GT, Ch.24.
IX. Interlude
We have completed our examination of the
latest-written of the chapters listed prior to “The Great Revision” in Table 11-1.
Our examination so far, however, omitted consideration of Chs. 2, 3, and 6-9 of
what we call the TOC. The main reason for this is that these chapters changed
considerably after Galley1(III).
We need to make sure the following situation:
(i) As of June-July Keynes had Ch.1 of Galley(2), Chs.2-6 of Galley(3), Ch.7-19
of Galley(2), Chs.20-25 of Galley1(II) and Chs.26-28 of Galley1(III) with him
as the latest version (all the chapters belong to the TOC); (ii) there exists
no galley after Galley1(III); (iii) we have several sources of information on
how Keynes changed in the period between August 1936 and February 1936 (the
publication of the General Theory).
Therefore, we are forced to reconstruct
Keynes’s developmental process in the last phase by using item (iii) which
comprises letters and comparing “the latest version” and the General Theory.
What characterises August-October is the fact
that Keynes altered Chs.3 and 6-9 considerably (Ch.2 is an exception) and the
TOC into GT’s table of contents,
which, of course, accompanied great rearrangement. We will call this activity “The
Great Revision”. Section X deals with “The Great Revision”. Here we will bring
the developmental process from “The General Theory” to the General Theory into view.
Concerning October-December,
the material concerned is the
Michaelmas lectures, which will be examined in Section XI.
X. “The Great Revision”
Keynes continued to revise the galley even after
Galley1(III), as attested by the following evidence.
In his letter to Harrod (17 August 1935) he wrote: “Here
are the last two chapters of my book. ... But chapter 26 is too long, .... In
chapter 27 the emphasis hasn’t worked out” (JMK. 13, p. 542. The TOC has
28 chapters, while the General Theory 24).
From Keynes’s letter to Robinson (3
September 1935) we learn that he had spent several weeks rewriting Book I (Chs.1-3)
and Book II (Chs.4-9). And in his letter to Hawtrey (4 September 1935)38
he announces: “I have ... completed my re-writing of the first three books,
namely chapters 1-11” (JMK. 13, p. 576. The TOC ends Book III with Ch.11
while the General Theory Ch.10). In
his letter to Harrod (10 September 1935), we read: “I shall be here from
September 22 … up to the end of the month. ... by then I shall have finished
re-writing the chapters dealing with rate of interest” (JMK.13, p. 559).
This might be Chs.15 and 16. This bears fruit in GT’s Ch.14,
“The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest”.
We also know, from Hawtrey’s detailed comments, and
Keynes’s response (1 October), that Keynes had also embarked on rewriting Chs.15
and 16 of Book IV (Chs. 12-19).
On 10 October Keynes sent a letter to Robertson saying:
“I am now practically finished, and am sending my galleys to the printers to be
paged” (JMK.13, pp.523-524). This
means that Keynes had drawn up the table of contents of the GT.
We will call these activities “The Great Revision”.
In this activity Keynes carried out his rewriting (among others, Chs. 2-3, 6-10,
15 and 16) along the TOC, but his activity soon accompanied the decomposition
and realignment of the chapters concerned, which means that the product of “The
Great Revision” is virtually the text of the GT.
Due to the paucity of our
sources, however, we know neither when precisely Keynes compiled the table of
contents of the General Theory. He revised the chapters concerned so greatly that he might have felt the
need to rearrange them and draw up a new table of contents.
It might have been in
September/October that Keynes rearranged the whole galley in line with the
table of contents of the General Theory. What remains as a fact is that
Hawtrey, in his letter to Keynes dated 19 December 1935, made comments on the
proofs which is based on the table of contents of the General Theory,
for we find such a passage as “Own―rates
of interest. A renewed study of chapter 17 leads me ...” (JMK.13, p. 625.
GT’s Ch.17 deals with own-rates of interest while it
is Ch.19 of the TOC that does). Judging from this, we may reasonably suppose that the galley based on the
table of contents of the GT reached
Keynes in November.
It should be noted that
Chapters 6-10 of the TOC undergo substantial further change to reach the form
of the General Theory, and that there the arrangement again changes as a
result of Ch.22 of the TOC being shifted to become GT’s Ch.10.
Let us now examine Chs.6-9 of Book II, “Definitions
and Ideas”, and Chs.2-3 of Book I, “Introduction”.
1. Chapters 6-9
Book II of the TOC consists of Chs.4-9, of which Chs.4 and 5 were finalized
in “The Typescript”.
A. Chapters 6 and 7 ― Some
Fundamental Concepts
a. Revisions to the Formal
Structure
There are two points worth noting about the revisions - in terms of
formal structure - to Ch.6, “The Meaning of Income”, and Ch.7, “The Definitions
of Quasi-Rent, Saving and Investment”.
First, the two chapters are at the completion stage, not only in terms
of contents but also at the level of style, as far as the text in TOC is
concerned. Ch.639, the revised version of Ch.6, “The Definition of
Income”, of the Pre-First Proof Typescript, is slightly revised yet further in Galley2
and Galley3, and Ch.740 is slightly revised in Galley2.
Second, rewriting these chapters became Keynes’s main preoccupation in
August. As a result they combined to become GT,
Ch.6, “The Definition of Income, Saving and Investment”, with its “Appendix on
User Cost”.
Ch.6, consisting of five sections, was revised from Galley3 to the GT
as follows:
(i) part of Section I (JMK.14, pp.
401-402) becomes the corresponding passage (pp. 52-53) in GT, Ch.6, Section I, “Income”;
(ii) part of Section II (JMK.14, pp.
401-402) becomes the corresponding passage (pp. 67-68) in GT, Appendix to Ch.6, Section I;
(iii) Section
III remains unchanged in terms of style, but is restructured to form GT, Appendix to Ch.6, Sections II, III
and IV;
(iv) Sections
IV and V do not appear in GT. Section
IV dealt with the calculation of income in extreme cases, such as that of “a
product prepared long beforehand [which] necessarily yields up its fruits now
and is incapable of being stored up for a later date” (JMK.14, p. 413),
and “that part of the wastage of any piece of equipment which occurs by the
mere passage of time and irrespective of whether it is used or not” (JMK.14,
p. 414). Section V stressed the need to define income, saving and investment
consistently.
Ch.7, consisting of three sections is revised from Galley2 to GT
as follows:
(a) Section I, which deals with quasi-rent, is
dropped in GT;
(b) some of the arguments in Sections II and III dealing with fundamental
concepts in relation to long- and short-period expectation as well as the
actual result and also in relation to user cost, correspond to GT, pp. 60-64, which are almost identical
with GT, Ch.6, Section II, “Saving
and Investment”;
(c) GT, Ch.6, Section I, “Income” (pp. 54-60), in which user cost and
supplementary cost are discussed, was largely rewritten at this time.
With respect to the GT the above changes can be summarized as
follows:
(i) Keynes wrote GT, Ch.6 taking
up the contents of Sections II and III of Ch.7 of Galley2 and those of Sections
I and II of Ch.6 of Galley3 and reworking them considerably;
(ii) Keynes
wrote GT, appendix to Ch.6, following
the contents of Section III of Ch.6 of Galley3.
b. Theoretical and Conceptual
Revisions
Ch.6 (Galley3) and Ch.7 (Galley2) contain the core discussion, in terms
of TOC, of the definitions of fundamental concepts such as income, investment
and saving. These chapters are closely related to GT, Ch.6, which contains the core of the argument concerning
fundamental concepts.
Let us see
how Keynes changed the definitions of such fundamental concepts in order to
arrive at the final form. This task can be opportunely addressed by comparing the
Pre-First Proof Typescript with the manuscripts written before and after it, as
well as comparing Galley1(I) with GT,
Ch.6.
(i) The Typescript and the Immediately Preceding and Successive
Manuscripts
The definitions of fundamental concepts adopted in the GT can be
traced back to those in “The General Theory”. Let us look at how Keynes changed
the definitions as he proceeded from “The General Theory”, through the
Pre-First Proof Typescript, to Galley3.
The most important characteristics these manuscripts have in common are:
(i) income is defined as the realized
value of, and effective demand as the expected value of the sale proceeds;
(ii) income differs from effective
demand, even if the difference between the realized value and the expected
value of the sale proceeds is disregarded.
“The General Theory” ─ We have already seen the
formulations in Chapter 10, I.
Income (Y) is defined as larger than effective
demand (D) by the amount of windfall profit (F), while effective demand is
defined as the sum total of the quasi-rent (Q. meaning normal profit) and the
prime cost (E).
These formulations are peculiar to “The General
Theory”; in particular, the definition of windfall profit (excess profit) makes
no further appearance subsequently.
The relation between investment I, saving S, and consumption C is also
peculiar41 to “The General Theory”. Effective demand is composed of
consumption and investment. Income is equal to consumption and saving. By using
the definition of windfall profit we can obtain:
F = S - I (6)
As from “The Parameters of a Monetary Economy” Keynes stood by the
notion of investment-saving equilibrium. Equation (6), however, appears as a
consequence of his argument, though he does not state it explicitly in “The
General Theory”.
Keynes stresses that investment and saving should be
construed as “gross” concepts. Gross investment is defined as inclusive of new
investment, replacements, and repairs, while gross saving is defined as
inclusive of sinking funds.42
“The
Summer Manuscript” — In Chapter 10, II, we have already seen the
formulations (the notation follows “The General Theory”, except where
indicated):
The most significant differences between the Summer Manuscript and “The
General Theory” in the definitions are that in the Summer Manuscript:
(i) windfall profit disappears;
(ii) user cost, Us, is considered to be the difference between
effective demand and income;
(iii) income equals the sum of consumption and investment.
Keynes defines the difference between effective
demand (D) and the prime cost (E) as the return to the entrepreneurs, Qs1.
The income of the entrepreneurs Qs2, defined as the difference
between Qs1 and Us corresponds to quasi-rent in “The
General Theory”.
In the Summer Manuscript the fundamental concepts are defined in nearly
the same way as in Galley1(I). In both cases Keynes treats those concepts that include
user cost as “gross” concepts, and stresses that effective demand can be
defined as a gross concept. It is hard to tell exactly how Keynes defines user
cost. However, given the reference Keynes makes here to “the user cost of the
initial stock of capital goods” (JMK.13, p. 472), and, moreover, given
the fact that he explicitly adopts user cost in the definition of investment although
it makes no appearance in “The General Theory”, we can safely say that this is
a new concept.43
“The Pre-First Proof Typescript” — Keynes deals with the
definitions of fundamental concepts in Ch.6, “The Definition of Income”. The title
does not appear in the table of contents of “The General Theory”. This chapter
corresponds to Ch.6, “The Meaning of Income”, in the TOCs from Galley1(I) to
Galley3. That is, after some revision, this chapter becomes Ch.6 of Galley1(I)44.
Unfortunately the parts in the Pre-First Proof Typescript which correspond to
Ch.7, “The Definitions of Quasi-Rent, Saving and Investment” of Galley1(I), in
which the interrelation between the concepts concerned are discussed, are not
extant. However, on the basis of material reproduced in JMK.14 (pp.398-418)
we may express the interrelation as conceived in that Typescript, as follows45:
Y = A - Up (17)
Up = Sp -
E (18)
Qp1 = A - E (19)
Qp2 = Qp1 - Up (20)
where A is gross sales proceeds, Up user
cost, Sp the supply price, E the prime cost, Qp1
quasi-rent, and Qp2 net quasi-rent. Subscript p indicates the
Pre-First Proof Typescript. (Note: In the Typescript the argument is not
couched in symbols. For the sake of convenience we use them.)
As in Galley1(I), we might assume that the firm is completely
integrated. It should also be noted that “the cost spent on the maintenance and
improvement of the initial capital equipment”, B, which is important in the
Galley1(I) (see (β) below), is yet to appear.
Since the definitions of fundamental concepts in the Summer Manuscript
are for the most part closely carried over to Galley1(I), and since the
Typescript was written in between, we can safely say that the definitions in
the Typescript for the most part closely reflect the Summer Manuscript. (One
exception is equation (18), which defines user cost. This makes no appearance
in the Summer Manuscript.) In that case, equation (17) becomes the same as
equation (7), provided the definition of user cost is the same in the
Typescript and Galley1(I). Then, gross sales proceeds, A, becomes equal to
effective demand, D, and the equivalence Qp1= Qs1 is
obtained from equations (19) and (10). Moreover, Qp2 = Qs2 is
obtained from equations (20) and (11).
In the Typescript, the term “user cost” is defined as “the loss in the
prospective value of a plant due to using it as compared with not using it”46,
so we can conclude that the definition of user cost is established in the
Typescript. The supply price, Sp, is defined as “the lowest price
which the owner of the equipment will accept for its output rather than lay it
up”.47 By transforming equation (18) into the following, we find
that the supply price is, by definition, the sum total of the user cost and the
prime cost:
Sp = Up +
E (21)
(ii) Galley1(I) and GT
For Keynes’s definitions of fundamental concepts we need to attend to
how the concept of “user cost” is defined.
In Ch.6, there is no difference in content between Galley1(I) and Galley3.
In Ch.7, the same is true with respect to Galley1(I) and Galley2. We will
examine Ch.6 of Galley3 and Ch.7 of Galley2 below. It should cause no confusion
even if we term them collectively as Galley1(I).
Let us begin with the differences in fundamental assumptions between
Galley1(I) and GT:
(i) in Galley1(I) firms are fully integrated, but
not in GT48;
(ii) in Galley1(I), but not in GT, Keynes uses “B” to denote the
cost of the maintenance and improvement of the initial capital equipment. As we
shall see, this is a vital point which determines the differences in the
definitions of some fundamental concepts.
With respect
to (i), GT denotes a certain sum paid on purchasing finished output from
other entrepreneurs by A1. In Galley1(I), therefore, A1=
0 (for the sake of comparison we will assume that A1= 0 below).
The notation in GT is as follows:
A : the sale
proceeds of finished output either to consumers or to other entrepreneurs.
Assuming A1= 0, A equals the value of consumption.
G : the
actual value of capital equipment at the end of the period. In Galley1(I) this
is denoted by C.
G’ : the
greatest value of capital equipment at the end of the period which would have
been maintained had it not been used for production. In Galley1(I) this is
denoted by C’.
B’ : the cost which must be incurred to
maintain the value of capital equipment at G’.
User Cost — This is the opportunity cost of capital equipment
which current production requires. We will denote the user cost in Galley1(I)
by U1 and that in GT with U2. Thus:
U1 = (C’- B’) - (C - B) (22)
U2 = (G’- B’) - (G - A1) (23)
where B denotes the cost of the
maintenance and improvement of the initial capital equipment.
With A1 = 0, equation (22) becomes:
U1 = (G’-
B’) - (G - B) (24)
Equation (23) becomes:
U2 = (G’- B’) - G (25)
The difference lies in B. The expenditure on capital equipment installed
in the current period accounts for most of B, so that G - B is the value of
capital equipment which contributed to current production at the end of the
period. We now know that U1 is the opportunity cost of the
capital equipment which contributed to the current production. On the other
hand, U2 is defined in such a way that the expenditure on
capital equipment installed in the current period is deducted from it.
Therefore, it is inappropriate for the definition of user cost. (The definition
of user cost in Galley1(I) seems to be more appropriate than that in GT).
From
equations (24) and (25) we obtain:
U2 = U1 - B (26)
If U1 is a more appropriate conception of user cost than U2,
then Keynes makes an extra deduction of B from U1.
Income ― Income as conceived in Galley1(I),
which is denoted by Y1, is defined by:
Y1 = A + B - U1 (27)
Income as conceived in GT is defined by equation (7). If we
denote it with Y2, then:
Y2 = A - U2 (28)
By making use of equation (26), we obtain:
Y1 - Y2 = B - U1 + U2 = 0
Thus Y1 equals Y2.
Consumption, Investment and Saving — Consumption is equal to A in
the system with A1 = 0. Saving is defined as the excess of income
over consumption in both the integrated and non-integrated cases. The
definitions of consumption and income are the same in both cases, so that the
definition of saving is also the same.
In the definition of investment, however, there is some difference
between the two. Let us denote the conception of investment in Galley1(I) I with
I1, and that in GT with I2. Then we have:
I1 = Y - A + U1 (29)
I2 = Y - A (30)
From these we obtain:
I1 = I2 + U1 (31)
Thus I1 is larger than I2 by U1.
By making use of equation (27), equation (29) becomes:
I1 = B (32)
That is, the cost of maintenance and improvement of the initial capital
equipment equals investment Galley1(I). Keynes refers to the difference between
I1 and U1 as “net investment”. Let us denote this with I1n.Then:
I1n = I1
- U1 (33)
From equations (24), (32) and (33) we obtain:
I1n = G -
(G’- B’) (34)
This is the definition of investment in GT (see GT, p.
55). On the one hand, in Galley1(I) “gross” (“net”) concepts are defined as
inclusive (exclusive) of user cost, U1, while on the other hand, in GT,
“gross” (“net”) concepts are defined as inclusive (exclusive) of the
supplementary cost, V (which is defined as the “depreciation of the equipment
which is involuntary but not unexpected” (GT, p. 56)). Thus net
investment, I1n, in Galley1(I) corresponds to gross investment in GT,
while net investment in GT can be expressed as I1n - V.
The Factors of Production — In Galley1(I) the prime cost, which
we denote with E1, is composed of the amount spent on finished goods
(the main constituent of which is labour-cost49), and B (the main
constituent of which is the labor-cost required for production of investment
goods within firms).50 Thus the prime cost equals the
amount of money which the fully integrated firm pays for both the investment
goods which are produced and retained within the firm and the finished output.
It does not contain U1 and equals the factor cost, F, of GT:
E1 = F (35)
In GT, prime cost, which we will denote with E2, is
defined as the sum of the factor cost and the user cost51:
E2 = F + U2 (36)
The profit of entrepreneurs, as understood in Galley1(I), which we will
denote as P1, equals the income of entrepreneurs as understood in GT,
which we will denote as P2. This can be shown as follows. P1 and P2
are respectively defined by:
P1 = A + B - U1
- E1 (37)
P2 = A - E2 (38)
From
these we obtain:
P1 - P2 = B - U1 -
E1 + E2 (39)
If we make use of the equation B - U1 = - U2
(derived from equation (26)), as well as equations (35) and (36), then equation
(39) gives us:
P1 - P2 = - U2
- F + (F + U2) = 0 (40)
The concept of “quasi-rent” in Galley1(I) is dropped in GT. In
Galley1(I) Keynes distinguishes three kinds of time elements in variables: the
actual value, short-period expectation and long-period expectation. He uses (’)
to indicate the short-period expectation, (’’) the long-period expectation.
In the case
of quasi-rent, its actual value is called “profit”, while its long-period
expectation is termed “prospective yields”. The term “quasi-rent” is retained for
its short-period expectation, and is formulated as:
Q = P’+ U1’ (41)
where Q denotes “quasi-rent”.
Effective Demand — The definition of “effective demand” in GT differs from that in Galley1(I),
though the definition of “income” is the same. In Galley1(I) effective demand
includes user cost, U1, but in GT it does not include user
cost, U2. If we denote effective demand in Galley1(I) with D1 and that
in GT with D2, then we have:
D1 = Y’+ U1’ (42)
D2 = Y’ (43)
where Y denotes income. (’)
indicates short-period expectation.
In Galley1(I) Keynes explains the concept of effective demand as
follows:
... in contradistinction to income, effective demand is reckoned gross of
user cost, so that D = Y’+ U’. It is essential to reckon effective demand
gross, since it is the gross value of output which absorbs spending power (JMK.14,
p. 422).
In GT effective demand is defined as the “aggregate income which
the entrepreneurs expect to receive, inclusive of the incomes which they will
hand on to the other factors of production” (GT, p. 55).
From equations (42) and (43) we obtain:
D1 = D2 + U1’ (44)
In Galley1(I) Keynes argues that effective demand is important because
it contains user cost, and distinguishes the concepts inclusive of user cost
(such as quasi-rent and gross investment) from those exclusive of it (such as
income, profit and saving). In GT he defines effective demand,
investment, income, profit and saving as exclusive of user cost, and does not
use quasi-rent. This suggests that the role of user cost recedes somewhat in GT.
B. Chapters 8 and 9
Ch.8, “The Meaning of Saving”, of Galley1(I) corresponds to GT, Ch.7, “The Meaning of Saving and
Investment, Further Considered”. Ch.9, “The Meaning of Investment”, of Galley1(I)
corresponds to GT, Ch.8, “The Propensity to Consume: I. The Objective
Factors”. Overall, there is less change in the proofing here than in the case
of Chs.6 and 7.
a. Chapter 8
This chapter is extant in Galley1(I) form and
in Galley2 form. Each version consists of three sections. Section II of Galley1(I)
version, which criticizes Hayek’s theory of forced saving, derives directly
from Section VI of Ch.8, “Investment and Saving”, of the Summer Manuscript. In
Galley2 Keynes adds to this only a supplementary explanation to the effect that
net investment necessarily equals saving, and that the theory of forced saving
is an inappropriate application of Bentham’s theory to the state of
underemployment. In Galley2 Keynes rewrites his account of how a change in the
quantity of money brings about a change in saving through a change in
distribution52, but the content of the theory is unaltered.
In terms of formal arrangement, the transformation from Ch.8 of Galley2
to GT, Chapter 7, which has five
sections, is considerable. In GT Keynes adds Section I (which states
that the difference in terminology lies in the difference in the definitions of
investment and income) and Section II (in which he defines investment, and
criticizes Hawtrey’s definition of investment as exclusive of liquid capital,
as well as the Austrian School’s idea of capital formation and capital
consumption).
GT, Ch.7, III of Chapter 7
corresponds to parts of Section I of Ch.8 of the Second Galley53.
There is no difference in content between the two. GT, Ch.7, IV is virtually the same as Section II of Galley2. On the
other hand, GT, Ch.7, V was compiled
out of several parts of Ch.8 of Galley2 (JMK.14, pp. 428-429, pp.
432-433 and 434-436), plus some new passages (GT, pp. 82-83) which discuss
the relation between the granting of bank credit and the theory of
investment-saving equilibrium.
b. Chapter 9
In Ch.9, “The
Meaning of Investment”, Keynes argues that “financial provision”, by
functioning as saving, decreases net investment and causes stagnation. This
argument is already complete in both contents and even form in Section IV of Ch.8,
“Investment and Saving”, of “The General Theory”.
Ch.9 survives in Galley1(I) and Galley2. The only difference lies in the
point that in Galley2 Keynes adds Kuznets’ data of gross capital formation in the
U.S.A.
This is an addition to discussion of Clark’s study in the U.K. in Galley1(I). Ch.9 of Galley2
is incorporated into GT, Ch.8, IV.
2. The Introductory Chapters
The three chapters of Book I, “Introduction”, are: Ch.1, “The General
Theory”, Ch.2, “The Postulates of the Classical Economics”, and Ch.3, “The
Principle of Effective Demand”. (They are reproduced in JMK.14, pp.
351-352, 352-369, and 359-379 respectively.) Ch.1 is almost identical to GT, Ch.1.
A. Chapter 2
Ch.2 exists in the galleys from Galley1(I) to Galley3. Apart from a few
slight changes of expression, there is no difference between them. In the Great
Revision, moreover, there is no change in substance, although there are some
stylistic changes.
GT, Ch.2 has seven sections.
In Sections I and II, Keynes adds “a decrease in the marginal disutility of
labour” to the list of the means of increasing employment available to
classical economics (GT, p. 7). Apart from this, we see some minor
revisions of style and wording.
In Section
III Keynes states that the struggle over money-wages does not determine the
level of real wages. The section is the same in content as the corresponding
part (JMK.14, pp. 363-365) of Galley1(I), albeit with some stylistic changes.
Section IV, which deals with involuntary
unemployment, is the same in content as the corresponding parts (JMK.14,
pp. 366-369) of Galley1(I) although, again, there are some stylistic changes.
The only real difference is that in Galley1(I) Keynes discusses involuntary
unemployment from the point of view of the supply side of labour only, while in
GT he also discusses it from the point of view of the demand side for
labour. The argument in Section V of GT, which discusses the
implications of accepting the first postulate and rejecting the second, was
formerly included in Section IV of Galley1(I).
The argument
in Section VI, in which Keynes states that Say’s Law underlies the entire
classical theory, formerly “appeared in an abbreviated form” (JMK.14, p.
368) as Section I of Chapter 3 Galley1(I). In GT Keynes adds a quotation
from Mill to illustrate the classical economists’ belief in Say’s Law.
Section VII refers to three assumptions, namely:
(a) the real wage equals the marginal
disutility of the existing employment;
(b) there
exists no involuntary unemployment; and
(c) Say’s Law, on which the
classical theory depends, was newly written for GT. It is absent from
Galley1(I).
B. Chapter 3 ― Employment Function
The galleys
from Galley1(I) to Galley3 for Chapter 3 are extant, and share an important
passage (JMK.14, pp. 370-371), which can be formulated as follows (this
formulation is the same as that in the second of his 1934 Michaelmas lectures):
D = f (N) (45)
D’
= F (N) (46)
D = D’ (47)
where D denotes effective demand,
f (・) the state of effective demand, D’ the supply price, and F (・) the
employment function.
The level of employment is determined by these equations. This
formulation is basically the same as in the GT, except for the terminology.
In the GT equation (45) is called the “aggregate demand function”,
equation (46) the “aggregate supply function”, D the “aggregate demand price”,
D’ the “aggregate supply price”, and the value of D at the level of employment
determined by equation (47) “effective demand”.
Let us compare this formulation with the formulations in “The General
Theory”, the Summer Manuscript, and the Typescript. As we have seen, the
employment function in the three manuscripts was used not only as a supply
concept but also as an equilibrium concept. This duality is absent from Ch.3 (JMK.14,
pp. 369-378) of the galleys from Galley1(I) up to and including Galley3, in
which the function D = f(N) is treated as representing the demand side, and the
function of D’ = F(N) as representing the supply side. However, in the GT
the duality reappears, and characterizes its theoretical structure.
In the galleys from Galley1(I) to Galley3, Keynes argues that income as
a realized value differs from effective demand as an expected value by the
amount of user cost. As we saw above, effective demand is vital in determining
the level of employment because it includes user cost. Moreover, user cost is
important for the definitions of concepts such as investment, saving and
profit. In equations (45) to (47), D and D’ include user cost.
When we say that equations (45) to (47) are the formulation used in GT
it is with the proviso that in GT the definitions of effective demand,
investment, income, profit and saving have been changed in such a way that user
cost is not included. In GT Keynes explains the reason for this change
as follows: “since user cost is obviously dependent both on the degree of
integration of industry and on the extent to which entrepreneurs buy from one
another, there can be no definition of the aggregate sums paid by purchasers,
inclusive of user cost, which is independent of these factors” (GT, p.
24, fn.2).
XI. The 1935 Michaelmas Lectures
After “The Great Revision” how did Keynes proceed to work on producing
the General Theory? Did he make no further changes, or did he, rather,
make certain substantial changes? We must now address these questions. The
lecture notes taken by Lorie Tarshis in the Michaelmas Term of 1935 (14 October
- 2 December) are the only material for this.54
The lectures were not delivered exactly in accordance with the final
text of the General Theory, which indicates that Keynes rewrote the
galleys during and even after the lectures.
In the Michaelmas lectures of 1935 the theory of employment is
formulated in terms of the aggregate supply and the aggregate demand functions
(The time span here is confined to the short period in which capital equipment
and the technology of production are given).
Z =Ψ(N) (1)
D = f(N) (2)
Ψ(N) =
f(N) (3)
Equation (1) is the aggregate supply function. This relates the volume
of employment to the sale proceeds, the expectations of which induce entrepreneurs
to employ the corresponding volume of employment (Z is the cost of production
of the volume of output of N men).
Equation (2)
is the aggregate demand function. This relates the aggregate demand
entrepreneurs expect to encounter for their output to the number of men they
employ.
The volume of
employment is determined at the intersection between the two functions.
The aggregate demand, D, is composed of the demand
for consumption, D1, and that for investment, D2. When
employment increases, both aggregate real income and aggregate consumption
increase, but the latter does not increase as greatly as the former. This is
expressed by the function D1 = X(N). Demand for investment is
expressed by the function I = D2 = F(N). It follows that Ψ(N) - X(N)
= I, so that N depends on Ψ, X and D2.
The theory of investment here has two characteristics:
(1) The discussion of the marginal efficiency of
capital here is not so close to the treatment in the General Theory as
was the discussion of it in the lectures of 1934.
(2) With regard to the theory of liquidity
preference, in the sixth lecture (18 November) the precautionary motive is
dependent on the rate of interest, while in the seventh (25 November) it is
made to depend on income.
Besides these, the following points also deserve mention:
(1) The objective factors make their first
appearance so far as the lectures are concerned. However, the list here differs
somewhat from that in the General Theory. The salient differences are
that in the General Theory changes in the wage-unit are added and
changes in the rate of interest are replaced by changes in the rate of
time-discounting.
(2) The qualified items which are listed in the calculation of the
multiplier are not always the same as those in the General Theory.
(3) The discussion of “the relation between a change
in the money wage and effective demand” differs from that in GT’s Chapter 19 in terms of the order
and number of items listed.
(4) As the means of curing unemployment in the case where the two classical
postulates hold good, “improvement in organization” is added, though “improvement
in foresight” is not still mentioned.
(5) The definitions of various concepts, including user cost, attain the
final forms found in the General Theory.
(6) Keynes invokes a number of problems for the
Quantity Theory of Money which remain insoluble even if many conditions
necessary to make the theory hold good are added. The problems mentioned are
virtually the same as those discussed in the General Theory.
In his letter to Macmillan (9 January 1936) Keynes
writes: “I now have the exact size of the book for the leaflet, namely, xii
plus 403”.55
After 19 January or thereabouts, the General
Theory was out of his hands. It was published on 4 February.
Two tables are given here. One is Table 12-2 which shows how each
chapter of the General Theory was
developed. The other is Talbe 12-3 from which we can get the whole view of
Keynes’s Michaelmas lectures in 1932-35.
XII. Conclusion
In this paper we set ourselves two main objectives:
(i) to show how Keynes carried out the proofing process, and (ii) to separate
out its main features.
Concerning (i) the following points emerge from our
analysis:
(1) Galley1(I)
represents the most considerable revision work carried out on the topics
covered in the TOC. Galley2 and Galley3 represent stylistic revisions of Galley1(I).
(2) Galley1(I)
is composed of Chapters 1-19.56 The chapters except for Chs. 4, 5,
12 and 13 were completed in Galley1(I) both in contents and at the stylistic
level, as far as the TOC is concerned.
(3) The largest change after Galley1(III) occurred in “The Great Revision”.
The definitions of some fundamental concepts changed due to both the change in
the definition of “user cost” and a change in its treatment.
(4) In the Michaelmas lectures (18 November) the
precautionary motive is dependent on the rate of interest.
In the case of (ii) our main
concern was: What kind of significance do changes or struggles detected in the
latter half stage hold for our understanding of Keynes’s theory?
Here there are two major changes to point
out, one concerning the “employment function”, the other having to do with
fundamental concepts.
(1) Employment function
In “The General Theory”, the Summer Manuscript and
the Pre-first Proof Typescript, the employment function was used as both a
supply concept and an equilibrium one. This duality disappears in Galley1(I) up
to and including Galley3. However, in the GT it reappears, and overshadows
its theoretical structure.
(2) Some Fundamental Concepts
We can summarize the relation between the
definitions of fundamental concepts in Galley1(I) and in the GT as
follows:
(i) The difference in effective
demand, investment and prime cost in definition depends on whether they include
user cost (Galley1(I)) or not (the GT);
(ii) the definitions of income, profit and saving are the same;
(iii) the equation U2 = U1 - B is vital to the
relation.
1) Cf. JMK.14, p.351. As precursors of
Chapter 5, in fact, there survive three versions written a little before the
Typescript.
2)
In Lord Keynes’s Letters to Daniel Macmillan, British
Library.
3) The original is Q (O). Cf. JMK.14, p.387.
4) JMK.13, pp. 525-526.
5) JMK.13, pp. 496-506.
6) JMK.13, pp. 484-485.
7) Robertson did not receive the chapter
corresponding to GT, Ch.10, “The
Marginal Propensity to Consume and the Multiplier”. The correspondence on the
galleys continued until March 1935. Robertson (3 February 1935) remarked “I’ve
found it extremely hard to see the wood for the trees”, and (10 February) wrote
that “a large part of your theoretical structure is … mumbo-jumbo!” The only
chapters to that Robertson agreed were Chs.14 and 17, for Robertson regarded
the liquidity preference theory as an alternative version to the loanable fund
doctrine. See Moggridge (1992, p. 567).
8) See JMK.14, pp. 446-447.
9) See JMK.14, pp. 446-447.
10) See GT, p.90.
11) See JMK.14, pp. 448-449 and GT, pp. 93-94.
12) On Ch.19
we have comments by Robertson and Hawtrey (JMK.13, 508-511, 574-576, respectively).
13) JMK.13, p. 525.
14) JMK.13, pp. 496-506.
15) JMK.13,
p. 634.
16) The
discussion between Keynes and Harrod about the galley continued from July to
October 1935 (JMK.13, pp. 527-565). The serious issue was over the
classical interest theory. Keynes deemed the classical theory (the loanable
fund theory) incoherent, taking the rate
of interest to be determined by the equilibrium of investment and saving, given
income. Instead he insists upon the liquidity preference theory. Harrod recognized
some value in the classical theory. He agreed completely with the constructive
part of Keynes’s theory, but opposed his criticism of the classical theory
(Harrod held his stance thereafter, as is to be seen in Harrod (1969, pp.
173-174)). From Keynes’s point of view, Harrod still remained partly in the
world of classical economics. See especially JMK. 13, pp. 530-552. For
the relationship between Harrod and Keynes, see also Kregel’s paper in Harcourt
ed. (1985). Blaug (1985, p. 637) questions Keynes’s treatment of the classical
theory where he refers only to Marshall-Pigou’s theory, which deals solely with
the so-called “direct mechanism”.
Milgate (Eatwell and Milgate eds., 1983, Chapter 5) maintains that “In
adopting Harrod’s reconciliation Keynes sacrificed his [critical] argument
[developed in Chapter 15 of Galley1(I)] on the altar of the immediate success
of the [constructive] theory. This has had the unfortunate consequence …” (p.
89).
17) Pigou (1941, Ch.7) criticizes Keynes’s critique of Marshall ’s
interest theory, arguing that Keynes fails to recognize that Marshall advances a long-term theory in which
the level of employment is given.
18) JMK.14, pp.479-487.
19) Cf. JMK.14,
pp. 482-484.
20) Cf. GT, pp. 189-190.
21) JMK.13, p. 525.
22) This
finds confirmation in the fact that the formulation of the employment function
in both Ch.21 of Galley1(II) and Ch.20 of “The General Theory” is one and the
same (In fact, Dw as deflated by the wage unit is
used).
23) Here we assume that in The Great Revision Keynes came to adopt the
same functions as in GT. This can be
confirmed by the fact that Keynes used “the aggregate supply function” and “the
aggregate demand function” in the second lecture for the 1935 Michaelmas term.
Patinkin (1976, Note 14 to Chapter 8) erroneously states that the aggregate “supply
function” is found only in GT.
24) See JMK.13, pp. 309-326.
25) See JMK.13, p. 525. Pigou (1933) thinks that a cut in money
wages contributes to increasing the level of employment. Pigou (1941), who on
the whole accepts the system of the General Theory, stresses two
conditions for the classical view: (i) money wages must be flexible; and (ii) a
cut in money wages must contribute to increasing the level of employment (see
pp. 91-92). For studies which deal with Keynesian theories on the
presupposition that money wages are inflexible, see Iwai (1981, pp.128-129) and
Yoshikawa (1984, pp. 87-88).
26) See JMK.14, p. 504.
27) In Lord Keynes’s Letters to Daniel Macmillan,
British Library.
28) Chs. 26, 27, and 28 will correspond respectively
to Ch.25, “Notes on Mercantilism, the Balance of Trade and Foreign Investment”,
Ch.27, “Notes on the History of Similar Ideas”, and Ch.26 (the same title) in
the table of contents of “The General Theory”.
29) Clarke (1998, pp. 122-124) mentions Keynes’s
inclusion of Hobson’s theory in GT.
30) This letter, together with some other letters by
Keynes to which we refer a little later, shows that Keynes was making his last
revision.
31) JMK.13, p. 653.
32) JMK.13, p. 542.
33) JMK.13,
pp.406-407.
34) JMK.13, p. 407.
35) JMK. 29, p. 48.
36) JMK.13,
p. 653
37) JMK.13, pp. 650-651.
38) JMK. 13, pp. 576-577.
39) JMK.14, pp. 398-418.
40) JMK.14, pp. 418-425.
41) Cf. JMK.13, p. 442 and 436.
42) Cf. JMK.13, p. 435.
43) A possible origin is to be seen in the remarks in JMK.13, p.
431, (iii).
44) See JMK. 14, pp. 398-418.
45) Based on the remarks in JMK.14, p. 400 (fn.2) and 412 (fn.2).
46) Cf. JMK.14, p. 400 (fn.2).
47) Cf. JMK.14, p. 400 (fn.2).
48) Cf. GT, p. 55.
49) Because we assume a fully integrated firm.
50) Cf. JMK.14, p. 404.
51) Cf. GT, p. 53.
52) See JMK.14, p. 430.
53) JMK.14, pp. 425-427.
54) For
a chronological analysis of the 1935 Michaelmas lectures, see Hirai(2003,
pp.537-549).
55) Contained in Lord Keynes’s Letters to Daniel
Macmillan.
56) Robertson’s
letter to Keynes (3 February 1935) and Keynes’s response (JMK.13, pp.
496-520) are useful for an understanding of Galley1(I), in which the principle
of effective demand and the liquidity preference theory are debated. Robertson’s criticism of the principle of effective
demand (and the multiplier theory) can be seen in Robertson (1940, Chapter IX),
his criticism of the liquidity preference theory in Robertson (1940, Chapter
I).
Also see a
controversy between Harrod and Robertson. Roberston remarked in his letter to
Harrod (27 September 1934) that “if your line of reasoning is right, it makes
nonsense of everything which I have been trying to say for the last eight years”.
Harrod answered (3 October 1935) that “My only ray of sunshine is Maynard’s
book. … I agree with him (as against you) that his book …is pathbreaking”. See
Young (1989, pp. 75-82).
Keynes’s discussion with Hawtrey is noteworthy as well. The sources
before the GT are contained in JMK.13 (pp. 567-633) and those
after it in JMK.14 (pp. 2-55). The most important document is Hawtrey’s
comment to Keynes (JMK.13, pp. 567-576). In his letter to Hawtrey of 4
September (JMK.13, pp. 576-577), Keynes states that he is revising the
galley (reference is to the Great Revision), taking Hawtrey’s comment into
consideration. From examination of the Variorum we can confirm that Keynes at
this time revised as follows: (i) the quasi-rent was deleted (Ch.7 of TOC is
the main place in which Keynes makes revision); (ii) the concept of the
marginal efficiency of capital was applied to working capital. However, the
debate between the two remained fierce after the publication of the GT. See
Keynes’s letter to Hawtrey (24 March 1936. JMK.14, pp.14-18).
References
LKE: Hirai T. 2003, Looking at Keynes’s Economics from Multiple
Points of View, University of Tokyo Press
(in Japanese). LKE, x, y:LKE, Ch.x, Sec. y. (The short and
updated version is to be published from Routledge.)
SKE: Hirai T., December
1997-March 1999, “A Study of Keynes’s Economics” (I)-(IV), Sophia
Economic Review, 43(1[67-136], 2[13-121]), 44 (1[35-127], 2[29-96]). SKE, x,
y: SKE, Ch.x, Sec. y.
The Treatise I or TM.1: Keynes J. M. 1971 [1930], A
Treatise on Money I: The Pure Theory of Money, London , Macmillan (JMK.5).
The Treatise II or TM.2: Keynes J. M. 1971 [1930], A Treatise on Money II: The
Applied Theory of Money, London ,
Macmillan (JMK.6).
The General Theory or GT:
Keynes J. M. 1973 [1936], The General Theory of Employment, Interest and
Money, London ,
Macmillan (JMK.7).
Blaug, M. 1985, Economic Theory in
Retrospect, Cambridge
University Press.
Bryce,
R., “An Introduction to a Monetary Theory of Employment” (1935. Reprinted as JMK.29,
132-150).
Clarke P. 1988, The Keynesian Revolution in the Making 1924-1936, Oxford ,
Clarendon Press.
Eatwell,
J. and Milgate, M. eds. 1983, Keynes’s
Economics and the Theory of Value and Distribution, Dcukworth.
Harcourt,
G. ed. 1985, Keynes and His
Contemporaries, Macmillan.
Harrod,
R. 1969, Money, Macmillan.
Hecksher,
E. 1935, Mercantilism (trans. By
Shapiro, M.), George Allen and Unwin.
Hirai,
T. 2004, “The Turning Point in Keynes’s Theoretical Development”, History of Economic Ideas, XII-2, pp.
29-50.
Hirai,
T. (forthcoming). “How Did Keynes Transform His Theory from
the Tract into the Treatise? ― Consideration through
Primary Material”, The European Journal
of the
History
of Economic Thought. Vol.14:2.
Hirai, T. 2005, “How, and for How Long, Did Keynes Maintain the Treatise Theory?”, read at the ESHET
conference, Stirling , UK , June.
Hirai, T. 2005 “How Did Wicksell’s Theory of Cumulative Process Influence
Keynes and His Contemporaries?”, read at the HES conference, Tacoma , USA ,
June.
Iwai, K. 1981, Disequilibrium
Dynamics, Yale
University Press.
Kahn R. 1931, “The Relation of Home Investment to
Unemployment”, Economic Journal, 41, 173-198 (in R. Kahn 1972, Selected
Essays on Employment and Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
1-34.
Keynes J.M. 1939, “Relative Movements of Real
Wages and Output”, Economic Journal,
March.
Keynes J.M. 1973a, The General Theory and After: Part
I, Preparation, London ,
Macmillan (JMK.13).
Keynes J.M. 1973b, The General Theory and After: Part
II, Defence and Development, London , Macmillan (JMK.14).
Keynes J.M. 1979, The General Theory and After: A Supplement, London , Macmillan (JMK.29).
Keynes J.M. 1981, Activities 1922-9, Part 1 and Part 2, London , Macmillan (JMK.19).
Keynes J.M. 1981, Activities 1929-31, London , Macmillan (JMK.20).
Moggridge,
D. 1992, Maynard Keynes, Routledge.
Mummery, A. and Hobson, J. 1898, The Physiology of Industry, John Murray.
Patinkin, D. 1976, Keynes’
Monetary Thought, Duke University Press.
Pigou, A.C. 1920, The
Economics of Welfare, Macmillan.
Pigou, A.C. 1927, Industrial
Fluctuations, Macmillan.
Pigou, A.C. 1933, The
Theory of Unemployment, Macmillan.
Pigou, A.C. 1941, Employment
and Equilibrium, Macmillan.
Presley J. 1979, Robertsonian Economics, New York , Holmes &
Meier.
Robertson D. 1940, Essays in Monetary Theory, London , P.S. king & Son Ltd.
Robinson J. 1933, “The Theory of Money and the Analysis of
Output”, Review of Economic Studies, 1(1), 22-26.
Young, W. 1989, Harrod
and His Trade Cycle Group, Macmillan.
Yoshikawa, H., 1984, A Study of Macroeconomics, University of Tokyo Press (in Japanese).
* Faculty of Economics, Sophia
University , Tokyo . E-mail: hirai-t@sophia.ac.jp This paper
originates in Hirai (1997-1999, Chs.13 and 14). The earlier version was read at
the International Conference on the Cambridge
School , Hitotsubashi Univ. ,
20-23 March 2006. I am grateful for invaluable comments, among others, by
Profs. Maria Cristina
Marcuzzo (Univ. of Rome <La Sapienza>), Roger Backhouse (Univ. of
Birmingham), Mauro Boianovsky (Univ. of Brasilia), and Dr Eleonora Sanfilippo
(Univ. of Rome <La Sapienza>).