<Draft>
To
What Degree Did Keynes Approach the General
Theory in 1933?
―
Searching for a Theory of Employment ―
I. Introduction
The aim of the present paper is to examine
Keynes’s developmental stage as of 1933. The year stands between A Treatise on Money (hereafter the Treatise) and the General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (hereafter the General Theory).
We need to begin
our story with very briefly explaining how we understand his theoretical
development from the Treatise up to
the end of 1932, which was examined elsewhere.
We argue that the Treatise
theory consists of two parts, one of which addresses the determination of
variables relating to consumption goods (Mechanism 1) and investment goods (Mechanism
2) in ‘each period’. The other part is formulated in such a way that, if they
make a profit (loss) in the current period, entrepreneurs expand (contract)
output in the next (we call this the TM supply function).
The Treatise theory can thus be expressed as
Mechanisms 1 and 2 working through Mechanism 3.1 This interpretation sees the Treatise
theory as a dynamic process of price levels and volumes of output.
Keynes defended
his dynamic theory until around October 1932, stressing the TM supply function.
This can be shown through examination of the manuscript “The Monetary Theory of Production” (JMK.13,
381-396), his controversy with Hawtrey, Robertson, the “Cambridge Circus”, etc.2
At the end of 1932, however, Keynes put forward a
simultaneous equations system in the manuscript, “The Parameters of Monetary
Economy” (JMK.13, pp.397-405), which
took the equality of investment and saving for granted, and adopted the
liquidity preference theory, a theory similar to the multiplier theory, and the
first postulate (though he retained some doubt about this last).
Although Keynes still clings to the idea of
the TM supply function, this manuscript nevertheless marks a turning point from the Treatise toward the General Theory.
We might say that
Keynes’s abandonment of the function shook the foundations of his theory up to
mid-1932, and the main components of the General
Theory were to be built as a consequence.3
Many interpreters of Keynes hold the view that in 1933 he
established the foundations of his theory of employment in the General Theory. We can not categorize
those views, to which we will refer in the notes concerned, so easily, for they
stand on different grounds which include their evaluation of the relation
between the Treatise and the General Theory. What is clear, however,
is that sufficient time and space has not been spent on studying the materials
concerned.
What we will aim at is to examine these materials in
detail, and to elicit the features of the real situation.
In this paper we will introduce two new concepts which
seem to be essential in understanding the three manuscripts in a consistent way
― “the pseudo-TM supply function” and “the pseudo-TM supply function mk2” (to be
explained below).
What matters here lies in our analysis of how Keynes
formulated his theory of employment or income, while still sticking to his pet
idea to the effect that the volume of output is determined based on the profits
earned.
To show the basic line of our results beforehand, we
recognise that Keynes stepped into the road which would lead to the General Theory, for he put forward
several models for determining the level of output or employment together with
some important concepts which were to comprise the General Theory.
We would like to emphasise, however, that Keynes’s models
suffer from several theoretical inconsistencies. By examining them, we can show
that Keynes in 1933 struggled to
formulate a new employment theory. In that sense we can safely say that his
theoretical framework is still far from completion.
This paper proceeds as follows. Firstly we will deal with
what he was writing for the projected book in 1933. For this, we have three
fragmentary manuscripts and three tables of contents. They are dealt with,
respectively, in Section II and Section III. In Section IV, we would examine
how Keynes argued his theory in the Michaelmas Terms.
In Section V, we would examine the relationship, in terms
of theory, between Robertson, Hawtrey and Keynes. The present paper ends with
the conclusion (Section VI).
II. Three Manuscripts
The manuscripts we
shall be looking into here are: “The Monetary Theory of Employment” (JMK.29,
62-66. Hereafter the First Manuscript); “The General Theory of Employment” (JMK.29,
63, 66-73, 87-92, 95-102. Hereafter the Second Manuscript); and the manuscript with
the same title as the Second Manuscript (JMK.29, 76-101 and JMK.13,
421-422. Hereafter the Third Manuscript).
1. The First Manuscript
The First Manuscript
is part of Chapter 6, “A Summary of the Argument So Far”, and is assigned to the
First Table of Contents. Two points are particularly noteworthy 4: the system of equations leading to the GT’s Chapter
3, and the “accounting period”.
A. A System of
Equations
The earliest system of equations determining the level of
employment is formulated here. It should be kept in mind that Ohlin (Patinkin=Leith,
1977, p.153) stated that in 1933 (or in the latter half of 1932) economists
began to treat output as a central variable in a monetary theory.
Keynes argues:
Thus the amount of
employment will be determined by a set of simultaneous equations which relate
together employment (N), prospective investment (I) and prospective consumption
(C), … :
N = f1 (Q) (1)
E = f2 (N) (2)
C = f3 (D) 5 (3)
D = E + Q = I + C
(4)
where f1 … may be called the Supply Function, f2 the Cost Function, and f3 depends on the propensity to save ....
If … we suppose the entrepreneur firms to know … f1, … f2, … f3 and … I, then … N
which they will offer will be determinate (JMK.29, 65).
In
his letter to Robertson (20 May 1933. JMK.13,
pp.307-308), Keynes tried to persuade Robertson that Robertson’s ‘hoarding’
equals Keynes’s ‘saving – investment’, which Robertson rejected (here ‘saving’
in the Treatise). Keynes also
referred to “[o]ld-fashioned saving” equal to investment. Judging from this, we
estimate that the First Manuscript must have been drawn up subsequent to the
letter, which has an expression: “my affection for the concept I – Q [=S]”
(p.308).
(a) The Components
Equation (1) differs from the TM
supply function as follows (the former concerns equation (1); the latter the TM
supply function):
(i) Q and N belong to the same period: Q to the current period and N to the
next;
(ii) N is determined by
the system of equations: N by a single equation;
(iii) Q and N
are variables: Q and an increment in output are variables;
(iv) Q
is expected by entrepreneurs: Q is realized.
Keynes, however, tends
to regard the two as playing a similar role, for he takes the view that
entrepreneurs determine the level of output (and that of employment) based on
profit6:
The aggregate amount of employment offered will depend ... on the amount
by which the sale proceeds of output … are expected to exceed their variable
cost (JMK.29, 64).
Keynes seems to
think that equation (1) works for the determination of the level of employment
in the same way as equations I΄ = C΄ (Q2) and R = H′(Q1) do in “The Parameters
of a Monetary Economy” manuscript (JMK.13, 403. Hereafter the PME manuscript)7. This, however, is not the case, for Q and N in equation
(1) belong to the same period:
... we are basing our conclusions about employment on the proper
criterion, … whether the result of spending money on employment and of selling
the output is expected to result in a larger net sum of money at the end of the
accounting period than if the money had been retained (JMK.29, 66).
Keynes compares
the “proper criterion” with “other criteria”:
Other criteria, such as the relation between the real output which a
given employment will yield and the disutility … of that employment [the second
postulate], or the relation between the real wages of a given employment and
the amount of its marginal output [the first postulate] ... are not appropriate
to the actual nature of business decisions … (JMK.29, 66).
Thus, rejecting
the two postulates8, Keynes retains the idea that entrepreneurs determine the level of
output based on profit. Given the difference from the TM supply function, and
yet the perceived continuity, let us call equation (1) the ‘pseudo-TM supply
function’.
Equation (2) may
be interpreted, following the explanation in Section II (2 (B)), as E = N.W (W
denotes the money wage).
Equation (3) is
the consumption function formulated for the first time.9
Equation (4) may
look like the equations Δ Q =Δ D - Δ E or Δ Q =Δ I +ΔF - ΔE of the MTP manuscript. However, it is not so
much an equation determining profit as one equalising supply and demand.10
Given I, the system determines the level of employment.11
(b) The Position of
the System
Let us examine the position of this system in the
light of Keynes’s theoretical development.
(i) The First Manuscript
maintains the idea that equilibrium of investment and saving determines the
amount of employment, so that equation (4) follows equation (4) of the PME manuscript.
(ii) In the Treatise
profit and prices are simultaneously determined, while the volume of output
changes with one time lag. In the MTP manuscript a time lag between profit and
the volume of output is assumed, without reference to prices. In the PMT manuscript
prices, the volume of output, and profit are simultaneously determined. In the First
Manuscript, the level of employment (the volume of output) and profit are
simultaneously determined without reference to prices.12
(iii) The TM
supply function virtually disappears in the First Manuscript, albeit a version
of I΄= C΄(Q2) and R= H′(Q1) of ‘Model 2’ of the PME manuscript is retained.
However, it does not work in the way he intends.
(iv) The
“aggregate demand function”, D = f (N) = X (N) + D2, where X (N) is the expected volume of consumption and D2 the expected volume of investment, of the GT is
fundamentally the same as the equation, D = f3 (D) + I, obtainable
from equations (3) and (4):
The following, on the other, can be derived from equations
(1) and (2):
E + Q = f2 (N) + f1-1 (N) = H (N)
where f1-1 is an inverse function of f1.
The function H (N)
describes entrepreneurs’ economic activities corresponding to the “aggregate
supply function”, Z= f (N), of the GT. Strictly speaking, it is not the same because of rejection of
the first postulate. Moreover, the system does not have a single concept such
as H (N). Thus we have some difficulty in establishing a link, and yet the
system might well be the first precursor of GT’s
Chapter 3.
B. The “Accounting Period”
In the First Manuscript
Keynes defines the accounting period as the span of time during which capital
equipment remains constant, and analyzes the economy in terms of it. It corresponds
to the Marshallian short run, and Keynes might implicitly have used this in
Model 1 of the PME manuscript.
Two points in
particular are worth noting here.
Firstly, while seemingly static, his analysis is in fact
dynamic. The values of the variables determined by the system belong to the
current period. Given the renewed values of the exogenous variables, the values
of the variables in the next period are determined in the same way. In each
period ‘a snapshot’ is taken, and the economy’s dynamic process is depicted as
a series of snapshots13:
The commencement of the next accounting
period will find the firms … [with] a different capital equipment, modified … by
wastage and obsolescence … and the new investment …. [A]t any given time the
productive processes … are decided in relation to the then existing capital
equipment. … [Thus] we are … in the closest possible contact with the facts and
methods of the business world …; and … we have transcended the awkward
distinction between the long and the short period (JMK.29, 65-66).
Secondly, the First
Manuscript assigns the role of connecting the current period with the next to capital
equipment, while the manuscripts up to the MTP manuscript attribute this part to
the TM supply function (and profit). Hitherto he had not shown any particular
interest in capital equipment (the Treatise had emphasized working
capital, entrusting fixed capital to Schumpeter’s theory), but now, with the
accounting period, he had the opportunity to reconsider capital and investment.
2. The Second Manuscript
This manuscript
consists of three fragments: one with no heading fragment, and two respectively
bearing the headings “Some Fundamental Equations”, and “Definitions and
Concepts Relating to Capital”. According to Moggridge, they belong to Chapters
1, 5, and 8, respectively, of the Second Table of Contents (to be examined
below).
In the Second Manuscript, Keynes emphasizes
the accounting period. He also uses equation (4) and the equation E = N.W ─ a variant of equation (2). Thus the Second
Manuscript stands on essentially the same ground as the First.
The features not recognizable
in the First Manuscript are:
(i) a function similar to, but a little different
from, the pseudo-TM supply function;
(ii) suggestion of the stability of the system;
(iii) acceptance of the first postulate;
(iv) heterogeneity of goods;
(v) two kinds of period concept.
(i) and (ii) are theoretically
important and related to Chapter 3 of the General Theory, while the
others are methodologically important and related to Chapter 2 ((iii)), Chapter
4 ((iv)) and Chapter 5 ((v)) of the General Theory.
A. The ‘Pseudo-TM
Supply Function mk2’
What characterizes
the Second Manuscript is a function14 resembling the pseudo-TM supply function. This seems to be
obtained by differentiating equation (1). However, this is not the case, for it
is excluded from the system determining the level of employment, and relates to
a stability condition. Let us call it the ‘pseudo-TM supply function mk2’.
We need to point
out a change in the definition of profit. In the Treatise profit was defined
as exclusive of normal profit, but profit here includes it:
… the excess of earnings over consumption corresponds to … Saving (S) in [the
Treatise]. It is not identically the same concept, since it does not
include the normal return to capital equipment … (JMK.29, 69).15
Along with this,
the concept “economising” appears, referring to “the excess of earnings over
consumption”, while “saving” is taken to mean “income minus consumption”.
In the Treatise,
earnings include normal profit, and consumption is assumed to be effected out
of earnings. Saving is the difference between earnings and consumption.
Contrastingly, “profit” in the Second Manuscript
is composed of normal and excess profit. It comprises income together with
earnings. Consumption is assumed to be effected out of income.
Thus, the definition of profit differs between
the two.16 Nevertheless, the idea that entrepreneurs determine the
level of output (and the level of employment) based on profit is retained:
… Δ N [an increment of employment] and Δ Q [an increment of
quasi-rent or profit] have the same sign. Further,
since Δ Q = Δ I - Δ S΄ [I is investment; S΄ economising], ... Δ N and Δ I - Δ S΄ have the same sign (JMK.29, 70).17
... the fluctuations of aggregate quasi-rent ... lead to fluctuations in
employment (JMK.29, 71).
Thus the concept relating
profit to the level of employment might reasonably corresponds to N = f1 (Q) in the First Manuscript:
Our first
fundamental proposition, namely
N and Q have the
same sign,
can then be expressed: –– the quantity of employment and the expectation
of quasi-rent during the employment [accounting] period increase and decrease
together (JMK.29, 76).
Profit and the
level of employment are considered to change within the same accounting period.
B. Suggestion of
the Stability of the System
Although the Second
Manuscript has not the system of equations of the First Manuscript, it has the
same ground as the First manuscript. Considering this and the pseudo-TM supply
function mk2, Keynes possibly used the pseudo-TM supply function mk2 similarly.
If so, contrary to Keynes’s intention it would not work for determining the
level of employment
Therefore something like the following solution would be
required: the pseudo-TM supply function mk2 could be separated from the system
for determining the level of employment and used for the stability condition.
An argument for
the stability of the system might then be suggested in terms of the pseudo-TM
supply function mk2:
… fluctuations in employment will primarily depend on fluctuations in
aggregate expenditure relatively to aggregate costs. This is the essential
feature of an entrepreneur economy (JMK.29, 90-91).
This proposition indicates
the stability of the system, since adjustment is assumed to be made within each
employment period. The pseudo-TM supply function mk2 might be interpreted as
adjusting the system.
However, Keynes develops
his analysis ambiguously as he deals with normal and excess profit. This,
together with a change of profit in definition and no systematic analysis,
makes it difficult to reconstruct the original model. Nevertheless, confining
changes to a minimum, we might formulate the pseudo-TM supply function mk2 as
follows:
Qi = I + C - (E + Qn) (7)
Δ N =ψ (Qi) (8)
ψ΄(Qi) > 0 (9)
ψ (0) = 0 (10)
where I denotes investment, C consumption, E variable
costs, Qn normal profit, Qi excess profit, N
employment, and ψ (・) the pseudo-TM supply function mk2.
In equation (7),
excess profit Qi is defined as the
difference between aggregate expenditure, I+C, and aggregate costs, E+Qn (Keynes in fact
regards E only as aggregate costs).
Equation (8) is the entrepreneurs’ behavioural function (actually
Keynes uses the sum of normal and excess profit, and uses the total level of
employment18). As excess
profit increases, increase in the level of employment accelerates (equation
(9)), while when excess profit falls to zero increase in the level of
employment comes to a halt (equation (10)).
The stability conditions
for the system are:
If N < N*, then I + C > E + Qn
If N > N*, then I + C < E + Qn
where N* is the equilibrium
level of employment.
If we call the
function relating the difference between aggregate expenditure and aggregate
costs to the level of employment the ‘excess demand price function’, the
stability condition is that the excess demand price is a decreasing function of
the level of employment (equilibrium is attained at the point where excess
profit is zero):
d{(I + C) - (E + Qn ) }/ dN < 0 (11)
To complete the model,
we need a system for determining the level of employment. This can be expressed
as
I + C = E + Qn (12)
D = I + C
(13)
E = W.N (14)
C = f3 (D) (15)
Qn = Qn (16)
In the Second Manuscript,
the “fundamental equation” is formulated as
Y = E + Q = C + I = D
where Y denotes income, E earnings, Q quasi-rents, and D
disbursement.
The Second Manuscript
has equation (14). Albeit not being in the Second Manuscript, equation (15) is verbally
expressed. With regard to equation (16), we read that “‘normal’ [return] is
constant for a given capital equipment” (JMK. 29, 69).
Excess profit is
excluded from the right-hand side of equation (12), and is defined as the
difference between I + C and E + Qn. So defined, it becomes zero at the equilibrium point.
Thus, given W, Qn, and I, the level of employment is determined.19
C. The First
Postulate
Keynes accepts this
postulate for the first time.
In his letter to Robertson dated 10
September 1933 (JMK.13, pp.310-313;
GTE/1/132) which contained criticism of Pigou (1933), Keynes called it the “fundamental
postulate of employment theory” approvingly.20
... the value of the marginal product is equal to its variable cost... (JMK.29,
72).21
D. The
Heterogeneity of Goods
In the Second Manuscript
this is emphasized:
...the concept of an average price per unit of output ... raises
precisely the same difficulties as to a quantitative measure of a
non-homogeneous complex, as does the measurement of real output itself. …
I find it, however, a matter of
considerable intellectual satisfaction that these partly insoluble difficulties
of quantitative description do not arise in our causal analysis, which is
strictly logical … and is subject, in practice, not to essentially insoluble
difficulties … (JMK.29, 73).
The unit measurement should be understood in connection
with the fact that Keynes, well-versed in the index problem, tries to avoid the
ambiguities of the general price level and output as a whole, finding new
concepts appropriate for the theory of employment. GT’s Chapter 4 (II) originates from this, apart from the concept of
“complexes” in the PME manuscript.
E. Two Kinds of Period Concept
In the Second Manuscript two kinds of period concept are compared: the
“production” (“investment”) period; and the “accounting” (“employment”) period:
The first forecast [covering the investment period] is that which … [an
entrepreneur] has to make when he decides to spend money on setting up a
capital equipment … The second forecast [covering the accounting period] is
when, being in possession of a capital equipment, he decides how much variable
cost to incur in working it … (JMK.29, 73-74).
This argument is
the origin of GT’s Chapter 5. The
first and second forecasts correspond to the short- and long-term expectations
respectively.
Keynes emphasizes
the accounting period because “all decisions to employ labour depend on
expectations covering this period (JMK.29, 74). This corresponds to GT,
50-51 where he stresses that the volume of employment is “determined by the
producer’s short-term expectations”.
He also stresses
the importance of distinguishing the accounting period from the investment
period, for failure to do so causes confusion:
[The investor’s] forecast relates to the hire which he expects to get
during each accounting period until the goods are worn out …. It leads…to a
great confusion to … regard the whole period from the first employment of
labour until the goods are finally worn out as constituting a single period of
production. … its appearance of logical completeness is illusory … (JMK.29,
75).
Keynes clearly criticizes Hayek’s (1931) theory
in which consumer goods and intermediate products differ only in production
stage.22
F. The Second
Postulate
The Second Manuscript
rejects it along with the argument of the First:
[According to] the Classical Theory …, given the amount of capital
equipment and the supply schedule of labour in terms of output, the volume of
output and hence the ratio of aggregate quasi-rent [Q] to the price of output [P]
tends to be constant ... [This] … must … [follow] from the second postulate.
Output will be pushed to the point at which the utility of the marginal product
is equal to the disutility of the marginal employment … only when we waive [it]
… [,] … [Q/P] can be supposed to fluctuate … (JMK.29, 70-71).
This can read as
follows. If the postulate is accepted, the economy reaches full employment. Applying
this to the equation O = NW/P + Q/P ─ a variant of the equation in the Second Manuscript (see
JMK.29, 71) ─, given O and NW/P, Q/P is kept constant. Unless Q/P fluctuates, output
(and employment) cannot fluctuate.
Besides these, the
Second Manuscript contains various other points of considerable significance,
including:
(i) Stress on fiscal policy (first
appearance in Keynes’s manuscripts) and low interest rate policy;
(ii) Support of a protectionist
policy;
(iii) Keynes’s persistent theme23 based on equations (7) - (10), that unless effective
demand increases, entrepreneurs cannot protect themselves from losses either by
increasing the volume of output24 or by reducing money wages25
(iv) The definitions of some central concepts, leading to an argument in GT’s Chapter 6 (II).
3. The Third Manuscript
The Third Manuscript,
dated December 1933, has Chapter 2, “A Difference between a Cooperative Economy
and an Entrepreneur Economy”, and Chapter 3, “The Characteristics of an
Entrepreneur Economy”, both being assigned to the Third Table of Contents.
The Third Manuscript is similar to the Second. Here we
focus on two concepts: effective demand and the entrepreneur economy. Effective
demand is closely related to the pseudo-TM supply function mk2, and the
argument for effective demand corroborates our interpretation of the stability
of the system (It has no passage arguing the determination of the level of
employment).
A. Effective Demand
The Third Manuscript
develops an argument based on the pseudo-TM supply function mk2, focusing on
“effective demand”.
Although the term first appears in the Second Manuscript (JMK.29,
97), the argument for effective demand appears here. The definition, which is
made in relation to the pseudo-TM supply function mk2, differs from that in the
General Theory.
Effective Demand may be defined by reference to the expected excess of
sale proceeds over variable cost ... [It]fluctuates if this excess fluctuates,
being deficient [excessive] if it falls short of [exceeds] some normal figure …
[I]n an entrepreneur economy the fluctuations of effective demand may be the
dominating factor in determining the volume of employment (JMK.29, 80).
Comparison is made
between sale proceeds and variable cost. The difference is defined as “profit”
in the 1933 three manuscripts. By subtracting “some normal figure [profit]”,
“excess profit” is obtained.26Then, the phrase “it falls short of some normal figure” refers to excess loss.
Effective demand is defined in relation to excess profit, moving in the same
direction.
If we take into consideration that “[an entrepreneur] will
increase his output if by so doing he expects to increase his money profit” (JMK.29,
82), the passage can read: if excess profit is negative [positive], effective
demand is deficient [more than sufficient], so entrepreneurs will reduce [increase]
the volume of output (and the level of employment); if excess profit is zero,
effective demand is in equilibrium, so entrepreneurs will keep the volume of
output constant.
Here Keynes does
not argue how the level of employment is determined, but discusses its
stability condition.
In the Third Manuscript
effective demand is discussed solely in terms of sale proceeds and variable
costs, which suggests that Keynes is only using a concept representing the aggregate
demand side.
Keynes criticizes
Say’s Law, presenting an alternative proposition:
… the classical economists have taught that supply creates its own
demand; … For [that] proposition, I shall substitute the proposition that
expenditure creates its own income …. (JMK.29, 80-81).
These, together
with a quotation from Marshall (1879), are the starting point for GT’s Chapter 2 (VI).
In the Third Manuscript,
Keynes endorses Marx’s view27 quoting from McCracken (1933):
The nature of production in the actual world is not ... a case of C - M -
C΄ … the attitude of business … is a case of M - C - M΄ (JMK.29, 81).
Keynes divides the
economists advocating this view betwee those asserting “the inevitable excess
of M΄” (e.g. Marx) and those asserting “the inevitable excess of M” (e.g.
Hobson) (JMK.29, 82). This is closely related to GT’s Chapters 3 (III) and 23 (VII).
B. The
“Entrepreneur Economy”
Keynes regards “fluctuations of
effective demand” as the crucial feature of an entrepreneur economy (see JMK.29,
85).
He examines the
relationship between the entrepreneur economy and “money”:
[A]nything in terms of which the factors of production contract to be
remunerated, which is not and cannot be a part of current output and is capable
of being used otherwise than to purchase current output, is, in a sense, money.
If so, … the use of money is a necessary condition for fluctuations in
effective demand (JMK.29, 86).
Money defined as something
used as a means of payment and of storing wealth is a necessary condition for the
fluctuations in effective demand. Although money alone does not cause the
fluctuations, no economic fluctuations would occur but for money.
In the monetary
system, argues Keynes, deficient effective demand occurs more frequently than
the opposite:
… the money … will ‘keep’ more readily than the output …(JMK.29,
86).
Keynes points out the
difference in property between goods and money. This, although only “carrying
cost” is mentioned, leads to GT’s Chapter
17:
... it is a characteristic of finished goods, … that they incur
substantial carrying charges for storage, risk and deterioration, so that they
are yielding a negative return … ; where such expenses are reduced to a minimum
… in the case of money (JMK.29, 86).
C. Shortcomings of
“Classical Economics”
The Third Manuscript
criticizes the Classical theory of employment and of interest.
In Keynes’s view,
the level of employment in a co-operative economy is determined in accordance
with the second postulate, but classical economics erroneously assumes that the
postulate is applicable to the existing economy.
He also attacks
Fisher and Marshall’s interest theory, in particular the “real rate of
interest”28, arguing that the idea that fluctuations of prices cause those
in the level of employment is, practically and theoretically, an error. The
role of effective demand is again stressed:
... it is not the prospect of rising prices as such which stimulates
employment, but the prospect of an increased margin between sale proceeds and
variable costs (JMK.29, 85).
4. An Evaluation of the Three Manuscripts
The above examination
shows that the three manuscripts reveal advantageous points in his theoretical
development while they expose theoretical inconsistencies.
A. The Essential
Points
The fundamental elements can be summed up thus:
(1) In the First Manuscript, under the concept of
“accounting period”, the system determining the level of employment appears for
the first time, using the consumption function and expressing all the variables
in terms of expected values.
(2) In the Second and Third Manuscripts, the stability
conditions are argued in terms of aggregate expenditure and variable costs.29
Point (1) is
important, for it leads to GT’s Chapter
3. As far as point (2) is concerned, the stability conditions are not taken
into consideration as such.
B. Several
Inconsistencies
The three manuscripts are flawed by several
inconsistencies.
(i) Keynes tends to regard the relation between the commodity market
analysis in the Treatise and in the General Theory as continuous.
This has to do
with the fact that Keynes transformed the TM supply function into first the pseudo-TM
supply function, and then the pseudo-TM supply function mk2.
This inclination
is to be found in the argument of the Second Manuscript (JMK.29, 71-73),
which might indicate a reversion to the Treatise world. Surprisingly
enough, it appears in GT,
77-78. This comes partly from his unconscious adherence to the idea of the TM
supply function.
Nevertheless, the
argument in the Second and Third Manuscripts can be properly understood only if
the function in question is interpreted as the pseudo-TM supply function mk2.
(ii) In the First Manuscript, equation (1) is in an awkward position, for
it contributes to determining the level of employment while it is also treated as
if the TM supply function.
(iii) In the Second and Third Manuscripts, normal returns are considered
to be constant, while the maximizing behaviour of entrepreneurs is
acknowledged.
(iv) In the three manuscripts there exists no concept representing the aggregate
supply side.
From our
investigations two clues for the interpretation of GT’s Chapter 3 can be gleaned.
First, a
Marshallian framework is adopted from the First Manuscript onwards. It is
reflected in:
(i) an equilibrium analysis by means of the demand and the supply functions
(although the supply side is unclear);
(ii) the stability
condition;
(iii) the period concept.
Second, Keynes probably
thinks that “windfall profit” becomes zero at the equilibrium point determined
in GT’s Chapter 3.
III. Comparison of the 1933 Three Tables of Contents
Keynes produced
three tables of contents in 1933:
(i) “The Monetary Theory of Employment” (seventeen chapters. JMK.29,
62-63. Hereafter the First Table of Contents);
(ii) “The General Theory of Employment” (nineteen chapters. JMK.29,
63. Hereafter the Second Table of Contents);
(iii) “The General Theory of Employment”, dated December 1933 (twenty-one
chapters with two excurses. JMK.13, 421-422. Hereafter the Third Table
of Contents).
1. The First Table of Contents
In Chapters 3, “Disbursement
and Economising”, and 4, “The Definition of Saving”, disbursement, economising
and saving might have been defined as expounded in Section II
In Chapter 5, “The
Propensity to Save”, the consumption function might have been expressed as
equation (3).
Chapter 6, “A
Summary of the Argument So Far”, is important because some fragments survive in
which the system of determining the level of employment appears for the first
time.
Chapters 7, “The
Theory of the Rate of Interest”, and 9, “The Schedules of Liquidity Preference”,
might have dealt with the liquidity preference theory, and Chapter 10, “The
Rate of Interest in Special Cases”, with the liquidity trap (no corresponding
chapter in the General Theory).
Chapter 13, “The
Relation between Real Wages and Employment”, may have had to do with Keynes’s
criticism of Pigou (1933) (See JMK.13, 312).
Chapter 14, “The
Influence of Changes in the Distribution of Aggregate Quasi-rent”, may have
argued the influence on the amount of employment by changes in the distribution
of aggregate quasi-rent, and equation (1) in detail:
The aggregate amount of employment offered will depend …
on the amount [of quasi-rent] … ― [albeit] … the nature of the
distribution of the aggregate expectation of quasi-rent between different firms
will probably affect the volume of employment, since the supply and cost
functions ... of different firms are not uniform (JMK.29, 64).
Chapter 15, “The
Magnitude of Changes in Employment Relatively to Changes in Investment”, might
have argued the multiplier theory for the first time, as far as manuscripts are
concerned. Judging from the fact that he developed the multiplier theory in The
Means to Prosperity (March 1933. JMK.9, 335-366), the table of
contents of the First Manuscript might have been written before it (and
possibly before the Second Manuscript).
Chapter 16, “The Theory of Prices”, may have been related
to the argument at JMK.29, 71-73.
Chapter 17 may have foreshadowed GT’s Chapter 23.
2. The Second Table of Contents
The only
differences from the First Table of Contents are found in Book I.
Chapter 2, “The
Characteristics of an Entrepreneur Economy”, deals primarily with the proposition
that changes in employment depend mainly on changes in aggregate expenditure
relative to aggregate costs.
Chapter 5,
“Fundamental Equations” deals with the equations Y = E + Q = C + I = D and Q =
D - E = I - (E - C).
Chapter 8 addresses
the accounting period.
3. The Third Table of Contents
The Third Table of
Contents comes closer to the contents of the General Theory than the
First and Second Table of Contents.
Chapter 1, “The
Postulates of the Classical Economics”, establishes the argument of the General
Theory.
The remarkable
features of the Third Table of Contents are found in Book II which comprises
“Quasi-rent”, “Income”, “Disbursement”, and “Saving”. Given that Keynes
stresses the “Essential Feature”, the definitions of quasi-rent, income,
disbursement and saving might have been the same as those in the Second Table
of Contents.
Chapter 8, “The
Propensity of Spend”, Chapter 10, “The Problem of the Rate of Interest”, and
Chapter 11, “The Concept of Liquidity Preference as Determining the Rate of
Interest”, might have established the arguments of the General Theory.
Chapter 12, “The
Nature of Capital”, Chapter 13, “The Conditions of Stability”, and Chapter 14,
“The General Theory of Employment”, are new, but with no surviving text.
Chapter 12 might have
been related either to GT’s Chapter 8
or Chapter 16 possibly the former, judging from the fact that the table of
contents of “The General Theory” in 1934 (JMK.13, 423-424) has no
chapter corresponding to Chapter 12.
Chapters 13 and 14
might have developed an argument explained, respectively, in Section II (2 (B))
and in Section II (1 (A)).
Chapter 15, “The
Supply Function”, is of particular interest. The function might have been
equation (1) rather than the first postulate. There are two reasons for this:
firstly, Chapter 3, “The Characteristics of an Entrepreneur Economy”, deals
with the “Essential Feature” (moreover, no concept corresponding to the
aggregate supply function of the General Theory); secondly, quasi-rent,
which disappears in the General Theory, is treated as an independent
chapter.
Chapter 16 uses the
term “Multiplier” for the first time.
Chapter 18, “The
Equations of Price”, may have been related to the argument in JMK.29,
71-73.
Excursus II uses
the term “Marginal Efficiency of Capital” for the first time. The sense in
which it is used differs from that in the General Theory, for even in
the “Second Undated Manuscript”, which follows this table of contents, the
concept differs from that in the General Theory.
IV. The 1933 Michaelmas
Lectures
The remarkable feature of the
1933 lectures30 (16 October – 4 December) is that the theoretical
framework there, if not completely that of the General Theory, comes close to it.31
In the fifth lecture
Keynes states that the income and price levels are determined in such a way
that Y = C + I (or I = S), which is the essential feature of the monetary
system (Y is income, C consumption, I investment and S saving).
In the sixth lecture the “psychological
law” makes its first appearance. Keynes then argues that given the state of
expectation and the propensities to consume and invest, a set of values for Y
and C is obtained which satisfy Y = C + I, criticizing the classical theory of
interest. In order to increase income the state of expectation, or the
propensity to consume, or the amount of investment must be changed. It was not
until this lecture that the determination of income was put forward in terms of
Y = C + I.
His new model appears more
concretely in the eighth lecture:32
M = A
(W, ρ) (M-1)
Y = C + I (M-2)
C =φ1 (W,
Y) (M-3)
I = φ2 (W, ρ) (M-4)
where M is the quantity of money, A the state of liquidity preference, W
the state of “news”, and ρ the rate of interest.
Y is given by
Y =φ1 (W, Y)
+φ2 (W, ρ)
Equation (M-1) shows that the
rate of interest is determined by the equality of the quantity of money and the
state of liquidity preference.33 This is essentially the same as
equation (M-6) of the PME manuscript. In the eighth lecture Keynes explains
his theory as follows: the income motive, business, precautionary motives
depend on business cycle, the facility of overdrawing and the rate of deposit interest
while the speculative motive on the state of bearishness.34
Equation (M-4) shows that,
given the rate of interest, the value of investment is determined. This differs
from Investment Price Theory (1). From the time of the PME manuscript Keynes had
maintained Investment Price Theory (2) as determining the price level of
investment goods. Then, in the Third Table of Contents, the concept of the “marginal
efficiency of capital” appears. Keynes seems to have distinguished, after the “Second
Undated Manuscript”35 (JMK.29,
111-120), this from the rate of interest, although the definition differs from
that in the General Theory.
Equation (M-3) and equation (M-2)
are akin to equations (M-3) and (M-4) respectively of the First Manuscript.
They share in common that given I, either the level of employment (in the First
Manuscript) or the level
of income (in the last lecture) is determined.
Concerning consumption, in the
fifth lecture Keynes regards it as a function of income and “windfall appreciation”, while in
the sixth of income only.
The most significant difference
between the model in the lectures and that of the First Manuscript lies in the
fact that in the former the pseudo-TM supply function is not used and
quasi-rent plays no role in determining the level of income, while in the latter
that function is used and quasi-rent plays a role in determining the level of
employment.
In the final lecture Keynes puts
forward “a better analysis” (Rymes, 1988, G34) for determining the level of
employment36:
M = A (W, ρ) (M-1)
N1 = f1 (N) (M-5)
N2 = f2 (ρ) (M-6)
N = f1 (N) + f2
(ρ)37 (M-7)
where N is the amount of
employment as a whole, N1 that in the consumption goods sector, and N2
that in the capital goods sector.
Thus Keynes argues that the
fundamental forces determining the level of employment are the state of
confidence, the propensity to consume, the state of liquidity preference, and
the quantity of money. This is called “The General Law of Employment” (Rymes,
1988, G35), in contrast to “The Particular Law of Employment” of classical
economics, which tells what national income will be in full employment.
Keynes intends the model of
equations (M-1) - (M-4) to determine its endogenous variables simultaneously,
which is closely related to the following developments:
(1) Acceptance of the “first postulate”.
(2) Adoption of the marginal propensity to consume
and the multiplier theory.
(3) Reference to the “fundamental psychological law”.
Besides the above, we see several
arguments which first appear in these lectures and seem to be the origins of
various aspects of the General Theory:
(a) Acceptance of the first postulate and rejection
of the second.
(b) A “choice of units” in terms of money value and
employment.
(c) Reference to short-period and long-period
expectations.
Although Keynes advances the
above arguments moving towards the General
Theory, we should not overlook that he still adheres to the argument that
ΔQ, ΔO, ΔN have the same sign, using relations such as ΔQ = ΔI - ΔS′ (S′, correspondent
to “saving” in the Treatise, is
called the “amount of economizing”).
It is not clear how this discourse is
connected with the main argument in which income (or the volume of employment)
is determined by Y = C + I. It seems to suggest a stability condition, but this
role is entrusted to the “fundamental psychological law”. The connection is
indeed complex. At any rate, evidently the role of quasi-rents re-defined here
as an inducement in terms of short-period expectations recedes into the
background as compared to his position in 1932.
V.
Robertson, Hawtrey and Keynes
In his letter to Robertson (26 October. JMK.13, 315-317), Keynes argued that Robertson’s spontaneous saving
is very near to his ‘saving’ in the Treatise
and he can see “no connection whatever’ between … [Robertson’s] revised meaning
of hoarding and the Marshallian K and income velocity V”.
Concerning the
second remark Robertson stated that “I am prepared to assert that on any level of abstraction all forces
acting on P can be expressed in terms of M, V, or R” (JMK.13, 318). The topic should be around M=KRP=RP/V. In an
unpublished paper, “Saving and Hoarding” (GTE/1/164-170), Robertson argued that
his revised hoarding and Keynes’s revised one are one and the same of the
Cambridge quantity theory.
It should be noted that throughout their correspondence
Keynes did not express his new theory as explained in the present paper.
We go to the
controversy between Hawtrey (1933) and Robertson (1933). They were very
critical of each other’s theory. Hawtrey criticized Robertson’s economics,
pointing out: the lack in reality; (ii) the neglect of stock of commodities
from a point of his economics of consumers’ income and outlay (See Hawtrey
(1926)). Robertson (1933), in turn, criticized Hawtrey’s theory, and emphasized
his theory’s advantage of “setting in high relief” analytically interesting
points.
Hawtrey (1932, 279) maintained his theory of consumers’
income and outlay, arguing that the quantity theory is of no use in the state
of disequilibrium. Hawtrey’s criticism of the quantity theory (see Deutscher,
1990, 36-39) is similar to Keynes’s one in the Treatise.38
Interestingly
Keynes, who was first influenced by Robertson in the mid-1920s, was influenced
by Hawtrey after the Treatise, and
moved forward thereafter, while Robertson and Hawtrey retained their
theories.
Robertson defended Pigou (1933). See JMK.13, pp.318-319. An interesting point
here has to do with the effect of a money-wage cut on employment. See GTE/1/148
(‘II Money wages and real wages’. Robertson), GTE/1/150 (2 Oct. 1933. Keynes),
GTE/1/151-152 (19 Oct. Keynes), GTE/1/159-160 (26 Oct. Keynes), JMK.13, pp.316-317 (26 Oct. . Keynes),
319 (Robertson). Shove was on Keynes’s side, saying that “It [Pigou (1933)]
struck me as the worst book on economics that I had read for a long time” (JMK.13, 321), and that “I have spent so
much time in the course of my life in abortive attempts to invent defences for
him” (JMK.13, 326).
With regard to Pigou (1933), Besomi’s
Archive has four letters from Keynes to Harrod (320, 322, 337, 343). In no.320
(10 Oct.) Keynes wrote: “To solve the question of the effect of the reduction of
money-wages in a most general case is hideously complex, and requires in my judgment
a different technique from that which you employ.” This was to lead to his
analysis in Chapter 19 of the General
Theory. In no.322 (27 Oct.) he said: “my criticism is prompted
by a lot of stuff I am now doing as to the inapplicability of many of the
classical assumptions to a monetary entrepreneur economy. Even if I am right, I
cannot expect you to agree until you have read some 100 pages or more of
unpublished material. In no.337 (30 Dec.) he wrote: “…I am finding it
impossible to make my points successfully without bringing in a quantity of my
unpublished theorising, …”. “unpublished material”, “my unpublished theorizing”
is what is examined in Sections I and II of this paper.
Finally Keynes opted not to write a
review of Pigou (1933) in the Economic
Journal, but published his observation as Appendix to Chapter 19 of the General Theory. Beveridge, who was asked
to write a review of Pigou (1933) in the Economic
Journal, waived the task. It was Harrod (1934) who eventually wrote the
review in the Journal.
VI. Conclusion
In this paper two concepts were emphasized for an understanding of Keynes’s
theoretical development in 1933: the pseudo-TM supply function and the
pseudo-TM supply function mk2 as important for understanding the three manuscripts
in a consistent way. We use the prefix ‘pseudo’ because the functions, in
substance, differ from the TM supply function, while we retain the phrase ‘TM
supply function’ because Keynes tends to regard them as continuous.
The three manuscripts reveal advantageous points in his
theoretical development while they expose theoretical inconsistencies.
The three
manuscripts constitute the origins of Chapter 3 of the General Theory.
They discuss both an equilibrium condition for the level of employment and its
stability condition, although no concept correspondent to the GT’s aggregate
supply function makes any appearance. In the First Manuscript Keynes put
forward for the first time a system determining the level of employment. This
was a breakthrough. And in the Second and Third Manuscripts, the stability
conditions are argued in terms of aggregate expenditure and variable costs.
Keynes’s way of
formulating the system, however, suffers from certain insufficiencies or
inconsistencies. Although we interpreted it as describing the stability
condition for the equilibrium level of employment, the argument in terms of the
pseudo-TM supply function mk2 is unclear. Among others, the argument in the
Third Manuscript which stresses effective demand is unclear, because it is
always made in terms of the sale proceeds and variable cost. The concept of “effective
demand”, moreover, is to undergo several changes before reaching the General
Theory. The arguments seen in the Second and Third Manuscripts are to disappear
thereafter.
These ambiguities or inconsistencies in Keynes’s argument reveals
that he is seeking his way towards a new employment theory.
We could also get some information through examination of
the three tables of contents.
The remarkable feature of
the 1933 lectures is that the theoretical framework comes close to that of the General Theory. The model in the
lectures and that of the First Manuscript clearly differ, for the former has no pseudo-TM
supply function, and determines the level of income without quasi-rent.
It is not clear, however,
how the discourse developed in the lectures is connected with the main argument
in which income (or the volume of employment) is determined by Y = C + I.
Finally, we examined how different, in
terms of theory, Robertson, Hawtrey and Keynes were in 1933.
1) For the theoretical framework of the Treatise, see Hirai (1997-1999, Chapter 7).
2) For this, see Hirai (2007b).
3) For this, see Hirai(2004).
4) In the three manuscripts variables are expressed in
terms of expectation.
5) Following the Second
Manuscript, we interpret “D” in the First Manuscript as “disbursement”.
6) The level of employment is presupposed to
be uniquely related to the volume of output through a short-run production
function.
7) C΄[H΄] denote a supply function of profit, Q1[Q2], in the capital [consumption] goods industry.
8) They made their
first appearances here.
9) Keynes referred to the consumption function
in “The Monetary Theory of Production” manuscript (JMK.13, pp.381-396. Hereafter the MTP manuscript), but in different
sense.
10) However, he
shows some ‘hesitation’ and places equation (4), seeing it as a definition of
Q, in equation (1). See JMK.29, 64. This ‘hesitation’ appears in the Second
Manuscript.
11) By solving the
equation, I + f3{f2 (N) + f1-1 (N)} = f2 (N) + f1-1 (N).
12) Keynes was to
tackle the problem of prices again, accepting the first postulate in the Second
Manuscript.
13) The “Economics
of the Budget Constraint” follows this idea. See Christ (1968), Tobin (1980)
and Turnovsky (1980).
14) See JMK.29, 76.
15) Following this,
normal return is stated to be constant.
16) The argument
that saving is necessarily equal to investment also appears in the Second Manuscript
(see JMK.29, 69). This can be traced back to the PME manuscript.
17) Judging from
the Treatise, Δ N and Q should be considered to have the same sign. Below
we put forward an argument with this change. Q is interpreted as excess profit.
18) We can
consistently interpret both the equilibrium and stability of the system only by
using an increment in the level of employment.
19) For the
propensity to save, see JMK.29, 100.
20)
His approval is also seen in the first Michaelmas lecture for 1933 (see Bryce
notes, p.B2-B3; Salant notes, p.M1; Tarshis notes, pp.J1-J2).
21) However, there exists no evidence showing the first
postulate’s incorporation into the system of equations (7) - (16). See also JMK.29,
101-102 as the origin of GT’s Chapter
2.
22) See GT,
76.
23) See JMK.29, 97, I and II. The same arguments
are in the 1933 Michaelmas lecture.
24 For a similar argument, see JMK.13, 384 (in the MTP
manuscript).
25) For a similar argument, see JMK.13, 369-370 (in
the Round
Table on “Unemployment as a World Problem” of June 1931.
26) Keynes does
not compare what adds “some normal value” to variable costs (i.e. aggregate
costs) with aggregate expenditure. Nothing like the aggregate supply function of
the General Theory appears here.
27) See also the
second lecture for his 1933 Michaelmas Term.
28) This criticism
might be directed against the “transition periods” analysis in Fisher (1911,
55-73) based on the rates of interest lagging behind prices.
29) Patinkin maintains that the Second and Third
Manuscripts are revisions of the Treatise, basing this supposition on Keynes’s
assumption of the TM supply function (1980, 20). Milgate (1983, 195) judges
that the three manuscripts of 1933 “re-express the [Treatise’s] Fundamental Equations … in terms of different
definitions”.
Amadeo (1989, 79) states, [in the Third Manuscript], “we
can first identify the central elements … of the principle of effective
demand”.
30) There
survive the following students’ notes: Bryce (pp.61), Cairncross
(pp.16), Fallgatter (pp.38), Tarshis (pp.39), Salant (pp.19), Thring (pp.18), and
Douglas (pp.15).
31) Patinkin judges that in the 1933 Michaelmas lectures the effective demand theory is argued for
the first time (Patinkin = Leith, 1977, 15-16). Dimand (1988, 166) states that
except for an investment theory, in the 1933 Michaelmas lectures all were “in
forms recognizably similar to those of the [General
Theory]”, pointing out that “[b]etween the Michaelmas 1932 lectures and the
1933 lectures, Keynes dropped profits … from its central position in his
theory, although it made a fleeting reappearance as A, windfall appreciation”.
Clarke (1998, 95) maintains that the 1933 Michaelmas lectures “gave a more
cogent account of the theory of effective demand according to the criteria of
professional economists” (he thinks that the inception of the theory can be
found in the 1932 lectures).
32) Kates (1998, p.140) argues that the seventh
lecture is decisive, for it reveals Keynes’s reading of Malthus (1802) which
made him step into the world of the General
Theory. Our judgement is that the direct influence
of Malthus upon Keynes’s thinking is rather limited, although he was stimulated
by finding deficiency in demand as the cause of unemployment there. I think
that (i) the theory in Malthus (1820) should be a forerunner of the Treatise theory as composed of the first
fundamental equation and the TM supply function rather than that of the General Theory, although Malthus
influences the General Theory on some
points. For further details, see Hirai (1997-1999, Chapter 9, Section 4).
33) “This
is the alternative to the two classical views [the loanable fund theory and
Marshall’s circularity] already discussed and seen to be abortive” (Rymes,
1988, G33).
34) See Rymes (1988, B55).
35) See Hirai (1997-1999, Chapter 9, Section 2).
36) “The real tool is thought, and … [these equations] are not a
substitute for it, but at most a guide …” (Rymes, 1988, G35). Also see Rymes (1988,
B59, J37, N17).
37) We see, moreover, f2
(ρ)= f3 (M/w) where w is a money wage.
38) The following
letter to Lydia (30 Oct.) mirrors Keynes’s state of mind: One can argue with [Hawtrey]
a long time on a perfectly sane and interesting basis and then, suddenly, one
is in a madhouse. … I have just been having a hopeless debate with [Robertson].
His mind, though frightfully ingenious, seems to me maliciously perverse. Again
it is like arguing with a madman” (Skidelsky, 1992, p.495)
References
Amadeo,
E., Keynes’s Principle of Effective Demand, Edward Elgar, 1989.
Christ,
C., “A Simple Macroeconomic Model with a Government Budget Constraint”, Journal
of Political Economy, February 1968.
Clarke, P., The
Keynesian Revolution and Its Economic Consequences, Edward Elgar, 1998.
Deutscher, P., R.G. Hawtrey and the Development of Macroeconomics, Macmillan,
1990.
Dimand,
R., The Origins of the Keynesian Revolution, Edward Elgar, 1988.
Eatwell,
J. and Milgate, M. eds., Keynes’s Economics and the Theory of Value and
Distribution, Duckworth, 1983.
Fisher,
I., The Purchasing Power of Money, Macmillan, 1911.
Harrod, R. F., “Professor
Pigou’s Theory of Unemployment,” Economic
Journal, March 1934.
Hawtrey, R., “Review: Banking Policy and the
Price Level by Robertson,” Economic
Journal, Sept. 1926.
Hawtrey, R., The Art of Central Banking, Longmans, Green and Co., 1932.
Hawtrey,
R., “Mr Robertson on “Saving and Hoarding” (II)”, Economic Journal, Dec. 1933.
Hayek, F., Prices
and Production, Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1931.
Hicks, J., “A Suggestion for Simplifying the
Theory of Money”, Economica, Feb.
1935.
Hirai, T., “Translator’s Commentary” for
Rymes (1989), Toyo Keizai Shinpousha, 1993 (in Japanese).
Hirai T., December 1997-March 1999, “A Study of Keynes’s
Economics (I)-(IV)”, Sophia Economic
Review, 43(1[67-136],2[13-121]), 44(1[35-127],2[29-96]).
Hirai, T. 2004, “The
Turning Point in Keynes’s Theoretical Development”, History of Economic Ideas, XII-2, pp. 29-50.
Hirai, T. 2007a,
“How Did Keynes Transform His Theory from the Tract into the Treatise?”,
European Journal of the History of Economic
Thought, XIV-2, pp. 323-346.
Hirai, T. 2007b,
“How, and For How Long, Did Keynes Maintain the Treatise Theory?”, Journal of
the History of Economic Thought, 29-3.
Hirai, T. 2007, Keynes and the Cambridge World – Social Philosophy and Economics, Minerva
(in Japanese).
Hirai,
T. 2007, Keynes’s Theoretical Development – from the Tract to the General Theory, Routledge (forthcoming).
Kates,
S., Say’s Law and the Keynesian
Revolution, Edward Elgar, 1998.
Keynes,
J. M., The Means to Prosperity, Macmillan, 1933.
Keynes, J.M., “Mr
Robertson on “Saving and Hoarding” (I)”, Economic
Journal, Dec. 1933.
Keynes, J.M., “A
Monetary Theory of Production” (in Clausing, Gustav ed., Der Stand und die nächste Zukunft der Konjunkturforschung: Festschrift für Arthur Spiethoff (with a
Foreword by J. Schumpeter. Duncker & Humblot, München, 1933).
Keynes, J.M., A Treatise
on Money I&II, Macmillan, 1930, 1971.
Keynes, J.M., The
General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, Macmillan, 1936, 1973.
Keynes, J.M., Keynes Papers,
(microfilm) Reel 33, GTE 1, King’s College, Cambridge.
Keynes, J.M., The
General Theory and After: Part I, Preparation, Macmillan, 1973.
Keynes, J.M., The
General Theory and After: A Supplement (to Vols.13 and 14), Macmillan, 1979.
Malthus, T., An Investigation of the Cause of the Present
High Price of Provision, J. Johnson, 1802.
Malthus, T., Principles of
Political Economy, 1820 (Sraffa, P. ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, Vol.2; Notes on Malthus’s Principles of Political Economy,
Cambridge University Press, 1951).
Marcuzzo, C.M. and Rosselli, A. eds., Economists
in Cambridge: A Study through Their Correspondence, 1907-1946, Routledge,
2005.
Marshall, A., The Pure Theory of Foreign Trade, The Pure Theory of
Domestic Values, 1879 (LSE Reprint)
McCracken (1933), Value
Theory and Business Cycles, Falcon Press, 1933.
Milgate, M., Capital and Employment, Academic
Press, 1982.
Milgate,
M., “The ‘New’ Keynes Papers” in Eatwell, J. and Milgate, M. eds., 1983.
Ohlin, B., “Some
Notes on the Stockholm Theory of Saving and Investment”, Economic Journal,
March and June 1937.
Ohlin, B., “On
the Slow Development of the ‘Total Demand’ Idea in Economic Theory”, Journal
of Economic Literature, September 1974.
Ohlin, B., “Stockholm
and Cambridge: Four Papers on the Monetary and Employment Theory of the 1930s”,
History of Political Economy, No.2, 1981.
Patinkin,
D., “New Materials on the Development of Keynes’ Monetary Thought”, History
of Political Economy, No.1, 1980.
Patinkin, D. and
Leith, J. eds., Keynes, Cambridge and the
General Theory, Macmillain, 1977.
Pigou,
A., Industrial Fluctuations, Macmillan, 1927.
Pigou,
A., The Theory of Unemployment,
Macmillan, 1933.
Presley,
J., Robertsonian Economics,
Macmillan, 1979.
Robertson,
D., Banking Policy and the Price Level,
Staples Press Limited, 1926.
Robertson,
D., “A Note on the Theory of Money”, Economica,
Aug. 1933.
Robertson,
D., “Saving and ‘Hoarding’”, Economic
Journal, Sept. 1933.
Robertson, D., “Mr
Robertson on “Saving and Hoarding” (III)”, Economic
Journal, Dec. 1933.
Robertson, D., “Industrial
Fluctuation and the Natural Rate of Interest”, Economic Journal, Dec. 1934.
Rymes, T. transcribed,
Keynes’s Lectures, 1932―35 ― Notes of Students,
Department of Economics, Carleton University, mimeo., 1988.
Rymes, T.
transcribed, edited and constructed, Keynes’s Lectures, 1932-35: Notes of a
Representative Student, Macmillan, 1989.
Skidelsky, R., John Maynard Keynes: The Economist as
Saviour 1920-1937, Macmillan, 1992.
Tobin,
J., Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity, Basil Blackwell, 1980.
Turnovsky,
S., Macroeconomics and Stabilization Policy, Macmillan, 1980.
Wicksell,
K., Interest and Prices (translated from the German, 1898, by Kahn, R.),
Macmillan, 1936 (Augustus M. Kelley, 1965).
# Professor,
Faculty of Economics, Sophia University, Tokyo. E-mail: hirai-t@sophia.ac.jp The paper originates in Hirai
(1997-1999, Chapter 10). The earlier version was read at the International
Conference on Keynes and Keynes’s Influences on Modern Economics, Sophia
University, Tokyo, in March 2007, and the HES Annual Meeting, George Mason
University, Virginia, USA, in June 2007. The author appreciates valuable
comments there.